Logo
    Search

    Mises Wire

    Articles, announcements, reviews, items of interest, interviews, etc., are posted to the Mises Wire.
    enMises Institute154 Episodes

    Episodes (154)

    Mises Institute's <em>Abolish the Fed</em> Documentary

    Mises Institute's <em>Abolish the Fed</em> Documentary

    In 1996, we produced a documentary titled Money, Banking, and the Federal Reserve. For the next ten years, we distributed copies all around the world, to our students, our members, and the public. Thousands of people were introduced to the evils of the Fed and central banking. At that time, not many people or organizations were calling for the abolition of the Federal Reserve. The Mises Institute was. And that hasn’t changed.

    Eventually, the documentary was posted on YouTube in February 2006, and it remains one of the Mises Institute’s most popular videos. We’ve had viewers from more than eighty countries. There’s even a Russian version of the film! From the most rural US town to Kathmandu, this documentary has exposed the dangers of central banking.

    Of course, a lot has changed since 1996.

    The Federal Reserve has seized numerous new powers and prerogatives, and the US economy has endured three more recessions, a major financial crisis, and forty-year highs in inflation. Another recession appears to be on the horizon, and much more inflation, too.

    Now is the time to create a new documentary that explains how the Federal Reserve continues to wreak havoc in the modern economy. It’s almost as if Fed economists want to impoverish us.

    We’ve interviewed several production companies and found one that believes in the importance of this documentary. That wasn’t an easy find!

    Our board has approved this important project, as well.

    We have everything in place to offer this film on Amazon. It will be free for all two hundred million Amazon Prime members. Making our film available to this kind of audience will be huge!

    We’ll also upload the documentary to streaming services like YouTube, Odysee, and Bitchute. And it will be on mises.org like everything else we create.

    The documentary will expose the Federal Reserve for what it really is: an enormous threat to prosperity, peace, and freedom. The Fed steals from the vast majority and gives to the corrupt few. The Fed makes it possible for the regime to wage endless wars. It’s a reason the government has grown to massive proportions. It threatens the livelihood of future generations. And ours, too.

    It’s a reason civilization is in decline.

    The Federal Reserve’s balance sheet quintupled in size after the 2008 financial crisis. And the Fed caused that crisis. Perhaps intentionally. Since then, the money supply has grown by more than $12 trillion. Half of that was printed in just the last three years.

    The Federal Reserve’s reckless money printing was touted as creating financial stability, yet Silicon Valley Bank, Signature Bank, and First Republic Bank still failed. Many more are on the same path.

    The Federal Reserve constantly moves its own goalposts. Remember how Fed economists declared that inflation would be “transitory” but then said we needed to “retire the word ‘transitory’” just a few months later?

    We need to retire the whole system, if you ask me.

    Politicians tell us that we need more regulation to fix the Fed. What we need is to abolish the Fed.

    The “experts” tell us that the Fed is our protector. Ha! It only protects the state, big banks, and their cronies.

    This is why we need to set the record straight. We cannot let the Fed be its own judge. We cannot let the financial news media paint a rosy picture of the government’s counterfeiting machine. Our new film will create an informative, watchable, and high-quality documentary approximately thirty-five minutes in length.

    I’m pleased to announce that Dr. Ron Paul has agreed to be in this film! There’s no way we would make a film about the Federal Reserve without Ron in it. His efforts to educate the world about the Fed’s manipulation of money are unmatched.

    The documentary will also feature several Austrian thinkers:

    Our friend James Grant, founder of Grant’s Interest Rate Observer and author of The Forgotten DepressionDr. Joseph Salerno, our Academic Vice President and the foremost Austrian scholar on sound money and business cyclesDr. Alex Pollock, Mises Institute Senior Fellow, former principal deputy director of the Office of Financial Research, and coauthor of Surprised Again!—the Covid Crisis and the New Market BubbleDr. Mark Thornton, Mises Institute Senior Fellow and one of the first economists to write about the housing bubbleDr. Jonathan Newman, the Henry Hazlitt Research Fellow at the Mises Institute, an impressive young scholar researching the role of central banking in expanding the size of government

    Their interviews will be combined with spectacular footage to illustrate the evils of the Federal Reserve. A top narrator will tell the story in an understandable fashion.

    The film’s goal is to introduce viewers to how the Federal Reserve causes inflation, business cycles, and economic disaster. We want to help people understand the urgent need to abolish the Federal Reserve system, and central banks in general. The more people understand the Fed is evil, the more pressure we build.

    Most people aren’t interested in the hundred-year history of the Federal Reserve, but they are interested in why their standard of living is lower, why they can’t afford to buy a house, and why they don’t have any money left over at the end of each month.

    As the Fed keeps telling lies, the rest of us know that something is terribly wrong. More and more people want to know what that is.

    Here at the Mises Institute, we know people have a lot of questions. We are the place where they can find the answers. This is why our film is so important.

    The film will cost $248,876 to produce. The crew will travel to Lake Jackson to film Ron. They will go to New York City to film Jim Grant. The other interviews will take place at the Mises Institute. Equipment, travel, and labor costs are the most expensive pieces of the documentary.

    Would you consider supporting this documentary? Every donor who gives $1,000 or more will be listed in the rolling credits at the end of the documentary. Of course, we welcome donations of all amounts.

    We want you to be a part of this important documentary.

    Join us in telling the truth about the Fed. With your help, millions of people will see the Fed for what it is: the enemy of liberty and prosperity.

    The Fed has dominated its own narrative for too long. Help us tell the world about the Fed’s failed record! Donate today.

    Mises Wire
    enOctober 09, 2023

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    Thanks to all of our generous donors who are participating in our 2023 Fall Campaign.

    Your continued support is vital and much appreciated. Donors are added daily.

    Won't you join them?

     

    Monday, September 25

    Abdelhamid Abdou Adam BattlesAdam DengAlan ZibelmanAndreas HübnerAnonymousAndrew WindsorArthur KnolleAnonymousBarb WhitemanBridget SantosCarl ChambersCarlos Aixerch MateuCharles CrawleyCharles DemastusChris Lingwall, In honor of Milton Friedman and Thomas Sowell who opened my eyes 50 years agoChris StriebeckChristopher SearsCristina FontaineDan ZipayDaniel Krivickas, In memory of True Liberty and Economic FreedomDarlene CorbettDave BennerDavid CardaronellaDavid NeilsonDavid ShaneDavid StefanDavide TafuriDione DurhamDon BellanteDonald SteeleDoug Hill, In honor of Ron PaulDouglas HaagaDustin TrammellEric HaleEzra GoldmanFred WitthansGerard EvenwelGreg KrabbenhoftGregory CitarellaHoward KillebrewHugh KendrickHunter Lewis

    Iain GreumJacob Coffin, In Honor of Hans-Hermann Hoppe and the book he wrote, Democracy: The God That FailedJames IrwinJavier Antonio Quiñones OrtizJavier Pantoja RomeroJay KorinekJeanne KacprzakJeffrey YerkesJerome GloeklerJerry KnarrJesse Cowell, In honor of William AndersonJesse DugayJim AgelopoulosJo Ann CavalloJohn BzoskiAnonymousJohn JollyJoris DebatsJoseph Wilchek, In honor of Tom WoodsJoshua BozzickKathryn HamiltonKenneth Woods, In memory of Milton FriedmanKerry SteenKevin AlonsKim StephensKristin JackvonyLawrence HamiltonLinda NicoLukas AbelmannManuel Heel, In honor of Manuel H.Mark MarkicMartin JacoviniMartin YoungMarvin Graham, In memory of Charlotte Kay GrahamMary SullivanMaureen MooreMiguel Gracia Arias, In honor of Miguel G. MoreuMike KeenanNancy Ore, In honor of the Mises InstituteNguyen Hoang DucNoah Van Horn

    Paris BleicherPaul BunevichPaul CerinoPaul JacobusPeter MichelPeter MorcombePeter RasmussenPitipong WantaRandy BoringRay SvobodnyReed ScercyRichard KrebsRichard MuldoonRichard Page, In honor of Lahaina CondoRichard PardoRobert CerfRobert ChandlerRobert YabutRoberto Mello, In honor of Dra. Sonia LafayetteRodger CottrellRoger WoodwardRonald BannerRonald LangdonSami PeltolaSayre PowersSheldon HayerSing ChungStelio PescialloStuart HicksTamara GoforthTheodore A. GebhardThomas CulverTimothy McMullanTony FulgenziTyke ConradyTyler HoxieTyler WambekeVernon MoretVictor SolaWalter BlockWilliam CampWilliam Winters

     

    Tuesday, September 26

    Alessandro ArtiniAlex KralAngela and Roger BoxAsh NavabiBarry LinetskyBart MillsBitcoin AnonymousBrandon Harnish, In honor of Paul MichelsonBurley StewartCarson McCurdyAnonymousDan HeinigDarryn CallDennis Gilman, In memory of Chesley H. GilmanEric RussellGary GodleyGary SchreyerGui LopesHarry MorseIvan Pedro Jimenez Correal

    James KernerJames RobertsJason SwiatekJoe KlecaAnonymousJohn PritchettJorge Oliveira DiasKatherine YoderKeith BrilhartLeonid GolenderLori McKenna, In memory of Charles ScarboroughLucas GoetzAnonymousMark McGuireMatthew Gunnell, In honor of LibertyMaxime Hupé

    Michael HarveyMichael MienkoMichael StankevichMiguel Ángel Alarcos TorrecillasNathan HarperNelly SmithRaul BritoRichard PaquetteRobert GainesRobert ZumwaltRobi ChatterjiAnonymousSkylar WebbSteven DusterwaldSteven MillerTakashi KimuraThomas LonerganVanner Ferreira da SilvaWayne K. FordZachary Bryson

     

    Wednesday, September 27

    Amy LePoreAndrew FitzgeraldAndrew QuinnAnonymousAntonio OrtegaAnwar M OsmanAshley Baxter, In memory of William Thomas CarlisleAttila RebakBambi KochBenjamin LemonBret LoganCharles CastroCharles HughesCharles Reifenberger, In honor of Paul KrugmanCharles TraugerChip MonroeCliff SlaterCorey CotterD Schertz, In honor of Rand Paul, I liked the robeDarren OlofsonDavid CrouchDesiree DumasDonnie MartinDoug JonesDouglas BrownellEdward WilsonGabe RoyerGabi Avni

    Gordon ClarkHayes GahaganHenk AllesIan SchmeisserJames CooperJames ThomasJason HallJason LubykJeff MillerJeffrey AbrahamJoe KerkesJohn WaresJoseph GillotteKaren SlingsKeith SipeKevin BurtKevin KylesLawrence GreenbergLisa BordelonLjubomir DimitrovskiMac TrenchMark BriggsMatthew BeanMatthew HaleMatthew WalshMitch Costin

    Naoya FuseNathan CharpentierPaul DidierPaul McCormickPaul SlobodnikPaul SullivanPeter CrabtreePeter de VietienPhilip HansenRaymond RondeauRichard Bird, In honor of all truth tellers—EverywhereRichard BrowningRichard HuberRichard WestrupRichard WilsonRobert StroheckerRonald WestStuart EgglestoneTab SchweitzerTed McKnightThomas BertrandAnonymousTim KnivetonTobie HallWalter CruseWilliam White

     

    Thursday, September 28

    Aaron LutherAgustin ArgaluzaAllen RossAna MartinAndrew LachajczakBart VanderhaegenBetzaida DurkinBoris KozintsevBradford WilsonBrent DresserBrent HarperBrett RoulstonBrian DuBridgeBrian McGlincheyBrian MurphyBruce SammutCharles ArmourCharles Naja, In memory of MUMChris DuFrayne, In memory of the U.S. DollarChris HindmarchCory HoldenDan NibbelinkDavid BarnesDavid CruseDavid PomeroyDean KocianDean McHenryDerek NelsonDorothea Burstyn, In memory of Alexander BurstynErik GuerraFrank GalushaFranklin JensenGabriel FancherGail MitchellGary CesarzGeorge ShchudloHarry ElliottHarry HerchertIra EpsteinJack WalshJames GreeneJan NiessenJeancarlo LopezJeff ReasonsJerome R AllenJerry LeCroy

    Joao Fernando Rossi MazzoniJoe LoiaconoJoel GibsonJohn CrissmanJohn DowningJohn FrabottaJohn GallagherJohn GrossJohn LarkinJohn RountreeJohn SattelJohn SchemppJohn SoutsosJonathan Huthmaker, In honor of Lauren SouthernJonathan HuthmakerJonathan MerrittJoseph CammJoseph GeorgeJoseph M. StivalettaJoseph SpelmanJoshua Vincent, In honor of Saifedean AmmousJoy Brower, Remembering Robert LeFevre and the Freedom School in ColoradoJulio BaylacKegan WilliamsKen ChristianKen HowardKenneth RobinsonKevin ChristensenKyle ThomLina ThomasLinda McCraryLisa GanskyMadalyn PettenatiMag Martin Alois BrandnerMalcolm IllingworthMarcin WielochMark AllenAnonymousMark SanchezAnonymousAnonymousMichael DurnwaldMichael ElwellMichael HouzeMichael JeffersonMichael Solow

    Michael WoodsMike and Kelsey WhelenMitchell OelbaumMT WebbNasly UstarizNorman HansenPatrick ButlerPaul FrankAnonymousPaul McCormickPaul SullivanPaul TaggartPedro García Mateo, In Honor of Pedro Ga. MateoPeter NavarroPeyton GouzienR.H. Hartman, In memory of Murray N. RothbardRaymond Eatmon, In honor of Stefan MolyneuxRichard ArmstrongRobert BellRobert CzachorskiRobert DaveyRobert GrahamRobert LisiRobin DeaRon LynchRoshi KhilaniRoy SteenhoekRui RosaRW HobertSeth BenjaminAnonymousSteve FennoSteve MitchellSteve ReillySteven MichaelTerrence D Gallagher, In memory of Morgan James GallagherThomas MajewskiTimothy RydellTimothy RydellTony DickersonTreena LuchettaVance HayesVictoria SandbergVincent O'NeillVincent VanderbentWilhelm LaecheltWill Fuller

     

    Friday, September 29

    Aaron BrownAlan ForresterAlberto Gonzalez, In memory of Alexis A. GonzalezAllen DempsterAndrew CainAndrey MorozovArthur NationBarry KnightonBenjamin LawrenceBernhard StalzerBilly ArmstrongBitros GeorgeBruce BurtonBryce NygaardBud Stamper, In honor of PrisonersChris BoyceChristopher StevensClaudia AsensioClaudia StaplesClinton Athey, In honor of Lew, Murray, and LVM.Colby CouncilColin TurnnidgeDar GandhiDavid HoustonDENNIS M BLAIRDerek SchanilDirck StormDon SalonenDonald McKennaDoug WhiteEddie Allen, In memory of James AllenEdmund BuckleyErick SepúlvedaErik OlsovskyErnesto OrtizAnonymousFrank GrahamGary GeddensAnonymousGeorge Miller-DavisGlenn RisoloGraham HarrowerGregg HunterGregg VoosGustavo Hincapie

    Hjalti KjartanssonIan RossiJames Mosher, In honor of Joseph Schumpeter and Ludwig von MisesJames VorisJamie Sargeson, In honor of Murray RothbardJared WallJason BrownJennifer Cole, In honor of Teddy GrafJerry MarshallJohannes Van der WeideJohn CiccotelliJohn GoodJohn JaegerJohn SweeneyJonathan DoozanJonathan LawlerJoseph BratcherJoseph FeiferKathie DoughertyAnonymousLance PietropolaLanden TerrellLarry GoodmanLaurence RebichLes DunawayLeslie MaltbyLuke Carriere, In honor of Satoshi NakamotoMark BransonMark BurkMark PackardMatthew BiancoMatthew LorenceMatthew Lynn, In honor of Ludwig von MisesMatthew ThomasMax JiangMax PrugerMichael ByrdMichael DeGanMichael WilsonMike AlcarazMike MaddaloniMolly BrannonNasser El DebsNicholas West

    Olliver RobinsonPatrick BrannanPaul ChristensenPeter GardowPeter SpungRalf HeinRalph HughesRares HRenee DuquetteRicardo KilsonRichard KlabechekRick NeisserRiley Wipf, In honor of Jason James Wipf, my brother and guide.Robert MolinowskiRobert RoseRochelle WoychowskiRoman FresnedoRon WilharmRonald StauberShelly Benford, In memory of Louis GregorichStan UllerichStephen GorinSteven DigilioTerrell YonTerry ReaddickThomas DiazThomas FleresThomas Jon JensenThomas KirwanTimothy Hutson, In memory of Albert & Loyola HutsonTimothy PittTodd ConnellyTodd WallsTom FreyTom Jenney, In honor of Ludwig von MisesTsvetalin RadevVladimir PopovicWayne CrapellaWayne WilliamsonWilliam Johnston

     

    Saturday, September 30 AnonymousAlvin PlummerAndrea CabralAndrei BucurAndrei CristeaAndrew ClevelandBarry FunkBob CovyeauBrian LintzBruce MauCharles BrooksCharles DeladuranteyCharles LarsonCharles NovitskyCharles PerrielloChris DolanChris GrindrodChristopher DillinghamChristopher NawrotClinton EzekielConrad WolfgangConway HawnDaniel HerltDaryl LandsgardDavid BeglarDavid BrownDavid CassarinoDeborah Cunningham, in memory of Herman KahnDeborah S ThompsonDennis GilmanDevon AkersDjamchid AssadiDon LeufvenEbenezer HoweEdwin LeggoeGail EgnerGlenn Parish, in memory of Edward Allen ParishGregory Girolami, in honor of Edward J. SavioGregory ToddHal Howertonharry bollingHeinz BitterliJack WattJacob McKnightJames ArgiroJames Flynn, in loving memory of my mother, Donna Flÿnn

    James JudgeJames MackeyJan NarvesonJarod MinneyJason LibbyJason LovettJay Davis, in honor of Roy DavisJay SmithJeffery KeysJerald RukavinaJessica TimbergerJim FarleyJoel MostowJohn BusenitzAnonymousJohn JordanJohn MasonJohn ReynoldsJohn SwallowJohn TeitenbergJohn WilsonJoselu GiraldoesJoseph RichJoshua SoldnerJulie HartmanKent DawsonKevin CokerKevin P HamiltonKevin WaspiKurt WagnerL. Michael WattsLarry AustinLarry WoodsAnonymousLinda GunningLinda PowersLucille StainesLuis KaramMarco OoijerMark OlesMark OwenMark ThorntonMichael BonenbergerMichael English

    Michael WatsonMike HartmanAnonymous, in memory of Richard and Helen GladsonNathan HinesNathan RussellNorman Andrews, in memory of Samuel Edward Konkin III.Nuno Martim Vieira MartinsPenelope MymudesPeter ThomasPeter TowersPeter TowersRandall DunnRandalll BrannanRene SarmientoRichard PiekenbrockRob GilmorRobert BatemarcoRobert ChevakoRobert ChevakoRobert WalkerRodney PilbrowRoger YoungRosemary DaugustaSam Price, in honor of Tom WoodsSamuel BakerScott AsterScott GreenoughScott WeissShawn BrodofAnonymousSteve LatimerSusan BrownThomas LevinsThomas RogersTimothy MooreTracy JamiesonUlrich CarlVictor AzebeokhaiWayne Johnson, in memory of Harlan C. JohnsonWill SchwartzWilliam AndersonYann BongiovanniZack Rogers

     

    All donors will be listed on our home page this week. Recurring donors of $5 or more, or one-time donors of $60 or more, will receive a free copy of Ten Great Economic Myths by Murray Rothbard.

    Mises Wire
    enOctober 01, 2023

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    "Thank you!" to the generous supporters, below, who donated to our Fall Campaign. The best people in the world support the Mises Institute.

    The goal of our Fall Campaign is simple—to increase our Membership and our influence.

     

    Friday–Sunday, September 30–October 2 Mr. Lukas Abelmann,in Honor of Eugen RichterMr. and Mrs. George AdamsMr. Carlos AdaroMr. Robert AllenAngel Alarcon AlvarezMr. Raul AmaviscaMr. Paul AskinsAnonymousMr. Richard BaileyMr. Philip BakkerDr. Javier BardavíoAnonymousMr. Louie Dean BattlesAnonymous,in Memory of Boo the DogMr. Oscar BendeckDr. George Bitros, in Memory of Fritz MachlupMr. Daniel BledsoeDr. Walter E. Block,in Memory of Murray N. RothbardDr. Carla BoydMr. Paul BraccoMr. Shaun BradleyMr. Ken Brodeur,in Memory of Leon Roldolph BrodeurMr. Gary BrogochMr. Steven BuerkleMr. J. Michael BugglinMr. Scott BurkhardtMr. Michael Ray BurrisMr. Jason V. CalvasinaMr. Nathaniel CameronMr. Dennis M. CampbellMs. Carol CarnesMr. Anthony CarrionMr. Samuel Cartagena-SergenianAnonymousMr. Carl ChambersMr. Stephen ChaplinMr. John Ciccotelli,in Honor of Ludwig von MisesMr. Doug ClarksonMr. James Cleaver,in Memory of Virginia D. CleaverMr. John C. Clonts,in Honor of George RobertsMr. Mark ColemanDr. Pearl CompaanDr. Giacomo ConsalezMr. Michael CoreMr. and Mrs. Michael E. CoughlinDr. Carlos Cuervo-ArangoMr. and Mrs. Raymond E. CunninghamMr. Robert CzachorskiMr. Bryan DanaMr. John Dancey,in Memory of Hilmar "Bob" MuellerMr. Matthew DarlingMr. Charles DemastusJP DeVilliersMr. Tino DiazDr. Ljubomir DimitrovskiMr. Richard DinnenyDr. Richard DoehringMr. John DorickoMr. Pedro DorregoMs. Maureen Dowst, CPA, PLLCMr. Kevin DueckMr. Walter H. Duke, Jr.Mr. J. Richard DukeMr. Ryan P. DukeMr. Jeremy P. DukeMrs. Desiree DumasMr. Lester DunawayMr. Andrew DwyerMr. Bill EatonMr. Brenton ElisbergDr. and Mrs. Sam EslerFare FakaMr. Jim FarleyMr. David FieldMr. Gregory M. Fisher,Free Julian Assange!Mr. Alan FluckigerMs. Diana ForgyIn Honor of Mr. Martin C. FoxMs. Kim GabrielDr. Gerardo Garcia GorostidiMr. Gary T. GeddensDr. Elizabeth GesenhuesMr. Christopher GeyerMrs. Debra GoldmanMr. Michael Alexander GoldsteinMr. William GoodaleMr. Larry GoodmanMs. Sheila GrabnarDr. Marvin Graham,in Memory of Charlotte Kay Snyder GrahamMr. Frank GrahamMr. Oscar Eduardo Grau Rotela,in Honor of Fabricio TeránMr. Steven GreerMr. Andrew GuinossoMr. Douglas HaagaMr. Matthew HanerMr. Bradley J. Hansen

    Kelley Hansen,in Memory of Nathan YazzieMs. India Hargett,in Honor of Melva GilesMr. Geoff HarpurMr. Roderick M. HarrisMr. Michael HarveyMr. Charles T. HatchMr. Daniel W. HaubeilMr. Otto HavelMr. Daren HeboldMr. Scott Heddaeus,in Honor of Hans Sennholz, Professor, Grove City CollegeAnonymousMr. Harold HelbockMr. Claude A. HemmerMr. James HendersonMr. Piet HensenMr. Eric HillerAnonymousMrs. Deborah P. HolmesMr. Douglas HouckMr. Chris Huff,in Memory of Ayn RandMr. Earl M. HughesMs. Linda HuntoonMrs. Rebecca Hyink,in Memory of Doyle and Wanda BairdMr. Lawrence JacksonDr. Thomas Jon JensenMr. Dan Johnson and Ms. Randee LaskewitzMr. David JohnstoneMr. Doug JonesMr. Justin JozokosMr. Robert D. KaercherDr. Martin KamberMr. Peter KearneyAnonymousMs. Laurel Kenner,in Memory of M. Stanton EvansMr. Barry KnightonMs. Julie KnowlesMr. Richard KrebsMr. David KuehnMr. Vincent LaBanca,in Honor of the Mises InstituteMr. Rick A. La GreideMr. Daryl LandsgardMr. Andrew LeaverAnonymousMr. Stephen Lemmons,in Honor of Dave SmithMr. Nicolas LeoboldDr. Paul LeslieMr. Brian LewisMr. Barry LinetskyMr. Donavan LingerfeltMr. John LockeJaime Lopez DiazMr. Jason LovettMr. David J. LownMr. Travis LutherMr. Mark MacheyMs. Amy MacnaughtonMr. Michael R. MaherMr. Benedict MaliakkalMr. K. Scott MalickMr. Raymond MannMr. James MansfieldMr. Donald W. MarekAnonymousMr. John MasonMr. Tim McClayMr. Duke McClure,in Honor of Dr. Karen PalasekMr. Patrick McDermottMr. Brian McGlincheyMr. Scott McRuerMr. Joseph MerlinoMrs. Donna Merzi,in Memory of Robert J. MerziAnonymousMr. Jarod MinneyMr. David MitchellMs. Gail S. MitchellMr. Mark MitchellMr. Zachary MooreMr. Glennon T. MoranMr. Roberto MorenoMr. David MorganMr. Paul MoschidesMr. Richard MuldoonMrs. Karen MunseyMrs. Penelope MymudesMr. Gerald NachurskiMr. Brent NelsonMr. Joel NicoloffMr. Nathan NifongMr. Eric Nyuma,in Memory of Eric S. NyumaMr. Perry OfferMr. Pete OliverMr. James OrphanidesMr. Antonio Ortega AlbonicoMr. Jaime OrtizMr. and Mrs. Michael V. OrtonMr. Daniel Pack

    Mr. Pablo Palacio DuarteMr. Brian PanaskoMr. John W. PanchukMr. Uwe Paschke,in Memory of Henry HazlittMr. Douglas PeckhamDr. Pedro Alfredo PerezMr. Neal PhenesMr. Richard A. PhillipsMr. Tom C. PolkMr. John R. PorterMr. Steve PoteatMr. Ronald PrestonMr. William Primm,in Memory of Eva PrimmRaven Grove Press, LLC.,in Memory of Ludwig von Mises Mr. Matthew Rawlings,Mr. Matthew Rawlings,in Memory of Roy RawlingsMr. Matt RayMr. Richard ReevesMr. William ReminiMr. Roland M. RenneMr. Allen Ricks Dr. Eric RidgwayAnonymousMr. Glenn RisoloMr. Matthew RitchieKahlil RobinsonMs. Rosemarie C. RotellaMr. Joseph RothMr. Charles RoweMr. Arthur RoyDr. Harleston RunionMr. John RyanMr. Steven M. SadlerMr. Luis SalgueroMr. Rene SarmientoMr. Andrew SaundersMr. Norman J. SavinMr. Derek SchanilMs. Kimberly SchrederMr. Jeff SchroederMr. Karl-Michael SchumannMr. Eric SchummMr. William SchwartzMr. Michael SchwarzMr. Tab SchweitzerMr. David SchwendingerMr. Daniel SearerPark SeohaMr. Kelley F. Shippey and Ms. Donna SimpsonMr. Rafael Silva,in Honor of all the great pro-freedom Austrian economistsMarcel SmeetsMr. Jay L. SmithMs. Danielle StanleyMr. Joseph StandridgeMr. Daniel Stenabaugh,in Memory of Ludwig von MisesMs. Mary Beth StockAnonymousMr. Craig StoughMr. Paul SummersMr. James SummersMr. Jess SuterMr. Alejandro SzitaMs. Catherine TheuerMr. and Mrs. Peter Ruffin Thomas,in Memory of my parents, Dr. and Mrs. Robert Y.H. Thomas, IIIMr. Jesse Thomas,in Memory of Iysander SpoonerMr. Matthew Thomassee,in Memory of Charles McGowenMr. Neal ThompsonMr. Charles TraugerMr. Michael P. TusayMr. and Mrs. Timothy UrlingMr. Christopher P. ValleMr. David VarianMr. Gregory VasaleMr. Steve VenderMr. Martin VennerMr. and Mrs. Chase VentersMr. Jeremias ViverosAnonymousDr. Sharon R. WaiteMr. Craig WalcottMs. Lora WalkerMr. Paul WardMr. Paul F. WeberMr. Nathan WhitsonMr. Kevin WillardsenMr. Spotswood WilliamsMr. Michael R. WilsonMr. David WinansMr. Richard WolfMr. Adam WoodMr. Michael WoodsMr. Gennadiy YablonovskiyMr. Robert YabutMr. Jim YoungYukon GroupMr. Warren Y. Zeger

     

    Thursday, September 29 Mr. Zeke AbramsWeston ArgoMr. Billy ArmstrongMr. Benjamin J. AycriggDr. Biff BakerMr. Robert BarrMr. Julio BaylacMr. Ken BeersMr. Bryan BerklandTerry BirdsallMr. Simon BlöthnerMr. Travis BostMr. Shaun BradleyAnetta BuraczynskaMr. John BzoskiMr. John CarboneMr. Juan Carlos Cervellera,in Memory of Raquel and J.C. Cervellera, Sr.Mr. Thomas ColellaAnonymousDr. Pearl CompaanMr. David CruseMr. Michael CulpRobin DeaMs. Delia Patricia Del Riego de los SantosMr. Donald FannonMr. Anthony Favalessa,in Memory of Erma FavalessaMr. Wayne FordMr. Andrew GallagherMr. Matthew GannonMr. Carl GartsideDr. Theodore GebhardMr. Stephen GorinMr. and Mrs. Charles GoyetteMr. Claudio GrassMr. Allen HartungMr. Justin HawkinsMr. Paul HenningMr. Robert W. HobertMr. Peter HyattMr. David HynesMr. Pavel IlcikMrs. Sara IsenhourMr. Darius JankowskiMr. Guojie JiaMs. Virginia JohnsonSchelina JuleMr. Daniel KellyMr. John KellyMr. Ryan KennedyMr. Darryl KingMr. Jack M. KingDr. Rudolph KohnMr. Greg KrabbenhoftMr. John H. LandMr. Andrew LinknerMr. Thiago LoMr. Burt LockhartMr. Matthew LorenceMr. Roger LoriaMr. Dennis Marburger,in Honor of Dr. Richard E. MarburgerMr. and Mrs. Thomas McCrary, Jr.Mr. Dean McHenryMr. J.T. McPhersonAnonymousMr. George Miller-DavisMr. David MuellerMrs. Camila Navia,in Honor of Fabricio TeránMr. Eric Nelson,in Honor of Daniel NelsonMr. Richard A. NewellMr. Justin PerryMr. Fernando Pozo MolinaMr. John PritchettMr. Carlos Puerta,in Honor of LibertyMs. Margareta RaducanMr. Michael ReddMr. Walter RiveraMr. Zackary RogersMr. Ezio RomanòMr. Jerry SalamoneMr. Mark SanchezMr. Charles ScarboroMr. John F. ScheererMr. Karl-Heinrich SchieleMr. Philip Schipsi,in Honor of Walter WilliamsMr. Ethan SchweitzerMrs. Bretigne A. Shaffer,in Memory of Butler ShafferAnonymousMr. George ShchudloMr. Ralph ShiveDr. Lawrence SilverMr. Tim SmithMr. Jeffrey SprolesDr. John E. Staddon,in Honor of F.A. HayekMr. Robert J. StewartMr. Jade Sullivan,in Honor of Greg SullivanMr. Michael A. ThompsonMr. Gregory ToddAnonymousMr. Larie TrippetAnonymous,in Memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. and Mrs. Scott J. UlleryRobin VazZonghui WangMs. Elizabeth WernerMr. Marcin WielochMr. Fred WitthansMrs. Donna Zedler

     

    Wednesday, September 28 Happy AlexanderMr. Brian AllenMr. Jeremias Antunes,in Memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. Florin-Paul ArmeneanMr. Charles AwaltDr. Robert BatemarcoMr. H. Ronald BjorkmanMr. Eddie BlueMr. Daryl BortzMs. Molly BrannonM. BrierleyMr. Nathan BriggsMr. Keith BrilhartMr. John BubolzMr. Conor Bunn,in Memory of John BunnMr. Charles C. Burridge,in Honor of Jeff DeistMr. Bruce BurtonMr. Justin CardwellMr. Carter CobbMr. Sam CragerMr. John CrissmanMr. Alfred R. DavieMr. Dennis De FordDr. Adolfo G. de UbietaMiss Ruth DickensSwithun DobsonMr. Brent DresserMr. Mark EcklerAnonymousMr. Anthony FerrettiMr. Alan ForresterMs. Sandra FosterMr. Richard FuhrmannMr. Tony FulgenziMr. Jetlir Gashi,in Memory of all those who share knowledge and help us abolish all ignorance!Mr. Bill GoadMr. William L. GossMr. Scott GreenoughMr. Olav GreisMr. Carl Hanich,Thanks to Frank ShostakMr. Darren HargroveMr. Jake HemingwayMr. Marvin HillMr. Jeffrey HillMr. Len Hofferber,in Memory of Lennert and Eva HofferberMr. David HoffmannJ.R. HoyneMr. Adrian B. IbricMr. Jaime Jasso BachaMr. Kyle JorgensenMr. and Mrs. Jason C. KellyMr. David KeoghMr. Frederick KinchMr. Edward KottMr. Vincent KulinMr. Barton KunstlerMr. William LangMr. Thomas LonerganMr. Michael LucasAnonymous,in Memory of Michael C. Lukehart, Attorney at LawMr. Bill MarakMr. William McNelisAnonymousMrs. Deborah Miller,a Gift for my HusbandMr. Mack M. MullicanMr. Edward MurrayMr. Gary Nelson,in Honor of Andrew Galambos, Free Enterprise InstituteMr. Zachariah NevilleMr. Santo Laucer OrtizMr. Jeffrey ParkerMr. Gary PelledMr. John PerlMr. Steven PerlmanMr. Charles C. PickMr. Paul PinetteAnonymousMr. Sean PolicelliMr. Jon PoureMr. Alexander ProffittMr. Javier A. Quinones-OrtizMr. Thomas Ramsfield,in Honor of Edward SnowdonMr. Gary RichiedMr. Clark RollinsMr. Eric RowellMr. Bruce SammutMr. Josh SchwartzAnonymousMr. Jackson SepulvadoMr. Jeffrey ShawAnonymousMr. Bob SimeralMr. Stephen SkarbekAnonymousMr. Kees SpaanMr. Greg StuesselMr. Lee SutterfieldMr. Ray D. SvobodnyJordan TahiMr. Paul ThielDr. Daniel TirelliMr. Joshua Vance,in Honor of Ken VanceMr. James VeillonAnonymousMr. Michael WatsonMr. John WernerMr. Ronald L. WestMr. Chris Wilson,in Memory of Walter WilliamsMs. Janelle WolfMr. Larry N. WoodsMr. Sean YounkinMr. Henry Yuen

     

    Tuesday, September 27 Mr. Abdelhamid AbdouAnonymousMr. Nick AscherMr. Harry AsmussenMr. Duane AushermanJade BarkerDr. John BartelMr. John BeanMr. David BrewerMr. Stephen A. BrownMr. Garland Anthony BulluckMr. Lance CansinoGordon P. Clark, MDMr. Eric ConnerMr. Jeffery DegnerMr. Greg DensonMr. Aaron Diaz ChavezMr. David DustinOr EzraMr. Paul FarmerMr. Kyle FennerMs. Eileen FitchAnonymousMs. Lisa GanskyMr. Lawrence GreenbergMr. Nathan HarperMr. James R. HartjeMr. Christopher Holbrook,in Memory of Thomas Wayne CampbellMs. Kathleen Jagodnik,in Honor of Ron PaulPekko KovanenMr. Roger LohmannBozhidar MarinovMr. Michael McQuadeMr. Roberto Mello,in Memory of Olendina de Azevedo BarbosaMr. James MillerMr. Vladimir MorgensternMr. Keith NolanMr. John Allen Bennett NoveyMr. Bernhard PaierMr. David ReyesMr. Ian RossiMr. Carter RuessMr. Luigi Santos-HammarlundMr. Michael ScarbroughDr. Mark SmithMs. Louise S. ThomanJose G. Urrutia, MD,in Memory of Rollin K. and Andrew UrrutiaMr. Juan Carlos Vera,in Memory of Ludwig von Mises

     

    Monday, September 26 Mr. David AmonetteAnonymousMr. James ArgiroMr. David BakerMr. Jeff BarreDr. Jeffrey BilottiMr. Alan BlairMrs. Daniela BullrichMr. Joseph CammMr. Stewart CarrollAnonymous,in Memory of Heinz BlasnikDr. Michael Castle,in Memory of Thomas JeffersonAnonymousMr. Eric CrosbyMr. Thomas CulverMr. David DouglassMr. Michael DurnwaldMr. Peter C. EarleDr. and Mrs. Sam EslerMr. Alex FábiánAnonymousMr. David FerroMr. Paul GendreauDr. David GilmartinMr. John GroshMr. Gene GryzieckiMr. Toby GuilloryMr. Douglas HaagaAnonymousMr. Dan HallettMs. Courtney HansonMr. Edward C. HarrimanMr. Daniel HerltMr. Gustavo Hincapie,in Honor of Javier MileiMr. and Mrs. Chris HindmarchMr. Michael Hogan,in Memory of Terrence T. HoganMs. Angela HooverMr. Herbert H. HooverMr. Jasson HowellMr. Hal HowertonAnonymous,in Memory of Dale CooperMr. Andreas Huebner and Mrs. Maria Jose Silva Roman,in Memory of Antonio MartinoMr. William HusseyAnonymousAnonymousMr. Michael KelleherMr. James P. KernerDr. Ricardo Kilson,in Honor of Ricardo Almeida KilsonMr. Thomas KirwanMr. and Mrs. Nathan J. KleffmanMr. Charles E. LarsonMr. Darius LeshabaMr. Joseph LombardiMr. Fernando LourençoMr. John LoyS. LutchmeenaraidooMr. Christopher J. MaloneyMr. Mark MarkicMr. Neal MarstonMr. and Mrs. Eugene V. McCaffreyMr. Ryan McHaleMr. Timothy McMullanMr. Ray McMullenMr. Samuel A. MitchellWaco MooreMr. Tyler MooreDr. Richard MorrisMr. Jack MosesMr. Daniel MuheMr. John MulheranMr. Arthur NationMr. Christopher NawrotMr. Gregg ObbinkMr. Douglas C. OrtonMr. James PeltonMr. Rodney PilbrowMr. Alvin PlummerMr. Jim RadetichMrs. Charlot RayMr. Melvyn ReznickMr. Brett RoulstonMr. Steve RudhallMr. John E. RushingMr. Rogerio Russo,in Memory of American FreedomMr. Mark SandeAnonymousMr. Virginio Schiavetti,in Memory of Murray N. RothbardMr. Mikhail Serfontein,in Honor of Jesus ChristMr. David SherrerMr. Robert SmithMr. David SmithMr. Richard SpreadboroughMr. Henry A. Steddom IIIMr. John SteelMr. Christopher StevensMr. John StoesserMr. Peter StollmackMr. Ronald TamburroMr. Josh TaylorMr. Sean ThomasTerri TotzkeMr. Paul TrappMr. Vitalik V.Mr. Mike VandenbosMr. Tim Van HussMr. R. David Van Treuren,in Memory of Murray N. RothbardMr. Richard VincentDr. Sharon WaiteAugust WestMr. Bob WheelockRichard and Lupita WiggansMr. Adam WilliamsMr. Elmer A. WrightMr. Theodore WroblewskiMr. Katherine YoderMr. Martin YoungAnonymousMr. Alan ZibelmanMr. David ZientaraMr. Robert Zumwalt

     

    All donors will be listed on our home page this week. Recurring donors of $5 or more, or one-time donors of $50 or more, will receive a free copy of How Inflation Destroys Civilization by Guido Hülsmann.

    Mises Wire
    enOctober 03, 2022

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    "Thank you!" to the generous supporters, below, who donated to our Fall Campaign. The best people in the world support the Mises Institute.

    The goal of our Fall Campaign is simple—to increase our Membership and our influence.

     

    Saturday, October 2 Mr. Benjamin AbbottDr. William L. AndersonMr. Robert W. AndersonMr. Jorge AvilaKasey BakerMr. Yvan BampingMs. Sheila BarkofskeMr. Bruce BarronAnonymousMr. Mark BeadleMr. Steven BechankoMr. Chris BecraftMs. Christine BenderMr. Robert BergdoltMr. Daniel BlackwellMr. Randy BleyerMr. Howard J. BlitzMr. Alexander BogeMr. Michael BowmanMr. Jack BoydMs. Susan Breidenbach,     In Memory of JoAnn RothbardMr. Ian BrennanMr. Andrew BroomeMr. Bozidar BrownMs. Maryjane BrownMr. Michael BrownMr. Daniel BuchfinkMr. Edmund BuckleyDeirdre BuckleyMrs. Daniela BullrichMr. Michael BurksMr. John BusenitzMr. Martin CarlsonMr. Nicholas Cerri, IVMr. Michael CevallosMr. Daniel ChangMr. Mark ChenMr. Kerry ChhimMr. Ricardo ChoiMr. Ken ChristianGordon P. Clark, MDMr. Vincent ClarkeMr. Doug ClarksonMr. Jim CofferMr. Stacy ConawayDr. Christopher CourtneyMs. Jo-Ann CoyneMr. Charles CrawleyMr. Wilson CruzMs. Candice Cullman,     In Honor of Paul CullmanMr. Sergio CusimanoMr. Robert CzachorskiMr. Kevin DaleBhargava DattaMr. Thomas Dattenberg-DoyleMr. L. Michael DavisMr. Timothy DeeringMr. John DePasqualeMs. Jennifer DePierroDr. Ljubomir DimitrovskiDr. Daron DjerdjianMr. Daniel DonovanRichard DukeRyan DukeJeremy DukeMr. Brian DunbarMr. Mark DyerMr. Levi EdwardsMr. Javier Eguillor MonteroAnonymousMs. Kristy EmmertAnonymousMr. Jared EwingMr. Joel FishTJ FitzsimmonsMr. Julian FondrenMs. Katherine L. FooteMr. David ForsterMrs. Nancy Forster,     In Memory of my mother, Mrs. Elsa RuskanMs. Wendy FoyMr. Mike FrancoMs. Elizabeth FranzagoMr. Todd FrenchMr. Alan FrischMr. Thomas FrühbeckMr. Carlton FurrMr. Apple GaffneyMr. Rafael GallegoMr. John GammageMr. Michele GarauGenaro GarciaDr. Theodore GebhardMr. Arthur Germaine,     In Memory of the Confederate States of AmericaDr. Elizabeth GesenhuesRobbyn GibbsMr. Raymond GladueAnonymousMr. Gary T. GorskiMr. Peter GrassMr. Brett GrasseMr. Nick GravesMr. Kevin GriffithMr. Sean GriffithMs. Olga GurariyMr. Joel HadfieldMr. Kevin HagenMr. Kevin P. HamiltonMr. Christopher Hammond,     In Memory of Gerald E. Hammond, MDMr. Timothy HansonMr. Nathan HarperMr. Jeffrey HarringtonMr. Rod HarrisMr. Daniel W. HaubeilMr. Justin HayesMr. Paul HenningMr. Harry E. HerchertDr. and Mrs. James M. HerringMr. Kenneth HiltonMr. Barry HoffordMr. Logan HoldenDebra HolmesAnonymousMr. Douglas HunttingMr. John JaegerMr. Alfred KaltschmittMichael KimberMr. Thomas R. KnappMr. James KnightMs. Jan KoemanMr. Greg KrabbenhoftMr. Richard KrebsMr. Bruce KrietschMr. Karl Kunkle,     In Memory of Robert Delos KunkleMr. Brian LankoRenato LatiniMr. Steven Law,     In Memory of Ludwig von MisesMs. Kathryn LawatiDr. Michael Lesser,     In Memory of R. Henry LesserAnonymous,     In Memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. Matthew LinderMr. Barry LinetskyMr. Thomas LonerganMr. Kevin LongbergMr. Stephen LordMr. Harmon Lowman, IIIMr. John LupoRobin MacInnisMr. David J. MackDr. Mihai MacoveiMr. K. Scott MalickMr. Dennis MarburgerMr. Donald W. MarekMr. Mark MarkicMr. Dennis MarshallMrs. Sheri MatzMr. David MayesMr. Samuel MazzaMs. Jennifer McDonaldMr. Stephen McIntoshMr. Donald J. McKennaSilas McKenney,     In Honor of Brogan and Lydia McKenneyMr. Timothy McMullanMr. David MellerMr. Michael A. Mellott,     In Memory of Robert WenzelMr. Kurt MeurisMr. Steven MichaelMr. Christopher MiedzaMr. Reuben MillerMr. Peter MilneBern MlynczakMr. Jacob MollMr. Robert MontgomeryMr. Robert MoodeyMr. Timothy MooreMr. Roberto Moreno,     In Memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. Joseph Morton,     In Honor of Harold ShurtleffMr. Joe MossMs. Gwen MyersMr. Per Wilhelm MyhreMr. Richard NaethingDr. and Mrs. Jonathan NewmanMr. Javier NogueiraMr. Roger NoldMr. Christopher NoyesMr. Joseph O'DonnellAnonymousMr. Mike OrtonMs. Roberta PaganiMr. Randy PalmerPanagiotis PapalamprosMr. and Mrs. Dennis PavickMr. Matthew S. PerryDorel PetreMs. Sandy PierreMr. John PiperMr. Patrick PoolMr. Dan PricopMr. Alexander ProffittMr. Dimitrios PsemmasErin QuinnMs. Mona RabonMs. Mark RaftisMr. Rafael Ramirez-de-AlbaAnonymousMr. Scott L. Reavy, Jr.Sai Reddy,     In Honor of Austrian EconomicsMr. and Mrs. Hans RichnerMr. Francis RooneyDr. Richard RossMr. Brett RoulstonMr. James RuhlandMr. Glenn RuffusMr. John E. RushingMr. John RyanLou SamselMr. Carlos Sansoulet,     In Memory of Raul Carlos SansouletRobin SchaferMr. Bernard P. ScheurleMr. Thomas SchiblerMr. Jack SchlichtingMr. Vincent SchoenigMr. Richard SchwaabMr. Leland ScottAnonymousMr. Benjamin SeeversDr. and Mrs. Don W. ShepherdMr. Bob SimeralMr. Keith R. SipeMr. Henry SkawinskiJay SmithMr. Victor SobczakMr. Joshua SoldnerMr. Joshua SolisMr. Joseph SpelmanMs. Laurie SponzaMr. Ronny StagenKasey StanfieldMr. James SteinMr. Joseph StephensMr. Christopher StevensMr. Timothy E. StevensMr. Edward StevensonMr. Robert StewartMr. James SummersMr. Thomas SwansonMr. Robert SzymaszczykMs. Nicole TateMr. Michael J. TearneyMr. Peter Thomas,     In Memory of Dr. Robert Yates Haynes Thomas, IIIMr. Charles ThompsonMr. Todd ThurmanMr. Richard TimbergerMs. Shea TroyerMr. Matthew UnterfengerMr. Lukas van GinnekenMr. Eduardo A. Visbal,     In Honor of Maruja y NandoMr. Thomas VitzthumMr. Janton WaandersMr. James S. WagnerLaura WalkerMr. Glen WarnerMr. Anthony WarrenMr. George WashburnMr. Greg WatlandMs. Mary Watterson,     In Honor of Lowell McEntyreMr. Paul F. WeberMr. Scott WeissMr. Richard W. WilckeJT Wilcox,     In Honor of Nom DeguerreMr. Steven WilkinsonAnonymousMr. Adam WilliamsMr. Jeff WilliamsMarty WilliamsMr. Torgeir WillumsenMr. Richard WilsonMr. Robert WimsattKirby and Andra WisianMr. Randall WolfMr. Scott WoosleyJungho YooMs. Irene ZannisMr. Marco Zavala

     

    Friday, October 1 AnonymousHappy AlexanderAnonymousMr. Luis Fernando Mira AmaralMr. Thomas AmatoMr. James ArgiroMr. Donald ArmstrongMs. Donna AsternMr. Timotej AugustinovMs. Jordan AusmanGabi Avni,     In Honor of my son Nadav for introducing me to the Mises InstituteMr. Vincent BarberaDr. Francis Xavier Bardavío AraMr. Joseph BartlettMr. Lawrence BellandMr. Stuart BerkMr. Samuel BlackmanMr. Lawrence BlakelyMr. John BoharsikMr. Chris BoyceAnonymousMr. Juan Bueno TrillMr. Jochen ButheMs. Kimberly CarlileMs. Kim CastorMr. Joe CelkoMr. Joseph Chizik,     In Honor of Louis ChizikMr. John CiccotelliMr. James ClarkMr. Alistair T. CosterAnonymousMr. Judson CrabbMr. Justin DavisMr. Charlie DayGerrit DevolkMr. Zach DillonAnonymousMr. Thomas Dougherty,     In Memory of Mary Irene Fraire DoughertyMr. David DouglassMr. James DunavantMr. Lawrence DunnNasser El DebsMr. Ross FarisMr. Anthony FavalessaMr. Wayne FechtMr. James FedakoMr. Steven FennoMr. Jonathan FinckMr. Steven FinneyMr. Paul FosterMr. William FosterMr. Paul Furlong,     In Memory of my “uncle” Jerry, my father’s best friendBarend GehnerMr. Paul J. Gendron,     In Honor of Anita GendronMr. Niels GerbitzMr. Richard GlanzmanMr. George GoemaereMr. Ralph GoldwasserMr. Paul GreatsingerMr. Paul GreenMr. Hank GreerMr. James GrundyDr. Amy Hackney BlackwellMr. Wayne HagelbergMr. Stephen HanleyBlair HardestyMr. Charles HatcherHendrik HechtMr. Jake Hemingway,     In Honor of Ron PaulMr. Robert HeuermannBruce and Lynne HillisMr. Travis HolteJeff and Hannah HoodMr. Steve HowlandMr. Nicholas HuntMr. Gregg HunterMrs. Anna Jacka-ThomasMr. Eric JaenikeDr. Porter Jenkins,     In Honor of our freedomMr. Thomas Jon JensenMr. Guojie JiaMr. Richard JohnsonMs. Marjorie JonesMr. John JordanMr. Don KempelJohanna KleinMr. Lukas KoflerMr. Andrei KreptulDr. Jonathan Kroll,     In Honor of Jacob, Ellie, Joshua, Michelle, Levi, and RubaMr. Mark KronenbergHaris KurbardovikjMr. Don LadynMr. Noah LaineMr. William LangMr. Gaofei Lei,     In Honor of Ludwig von MisesMr. Herman LeusinkMr. Robert LewisMr. James MackeyMr. Chris MalamisuroDr. Allen MartinMr. Edward S. MatalkaMr. David Mateer,In Honor of freedomMr. Duke McClure,     In Honor of my economics professor who forever changed the way I see the worldMr. Keith McClardMr. Jeff McGannMr. Ryan McLinDr. Lawrence McQuillanMs. Nancy L. MeinersDr. Justin MerrittMr. Kenneth MetcalfeMr. Peter J. MichelL. MillerVladimir MonachovMr. Thomas MooreMr. Brent MorrowMr. August NapotnikMr. Andrew NappiMr. Christopher NawrotMr. Jacob NemchenokMr. Christopher Nizza,     In Honor of Ron PaulMr. Timothy O'LearyMr. Mark PackardMr. Glenn ParishMr. Walter PaulsonMs. Chrystyna PeddeAnonymousMr. David PomeroyMs. Selene PrideMr. Charrier QuinonesMr. Melvin Raab,     In Memory of Melvin C. Raab, Sr.Mr. Ethan RamseyMr. Brett RiggsMr. Edward RobertsonMr. Zackary RogersMr. Ezio Romanò,     In Memory of Luigi EinaudiMr. Joaquim Saad de Carvalho,     In Memory of Maria Helena F. SaadMr. Bruce SammutMr. Jason SaxonMr. Gary SchladerMr. Andrew Schoenherr,     In Memory of Howard SchoenherrMr. William SchwartzMr. Seth ShookMr. Stephen SkarbekMr. Peter SkurkissJay SmithMr. Stephen SmithMr. James SnyderGalen SoreyMr. Mark Spartz,     In Memory of Joseph Matthew Spatz and Grandpa Robert MergenMr. Jose StelleDr. and Mrs. Benjamin F. StickleMs. Marquita StoryMr. Emanuel Mark StrategosMr. Jason SylvesterMr. Samuel TamayoMr. Joseph TaylorMr. Dmitry TeyblyumMrs. Lina ThomasMr. J. Brian TraceyMr. Erik TukuaDr. Kirk Christian ValanisMr. Piet van den Boomen,     In Honor of Fam van den BoomenMr. Robert VestalMr. Robert A. VincentMr. Eric Von KaenelMr. Steve WallaceMs. Haley WatsonBlair WestfallMatt and Melissa WilliamsMrs. Susan WilliamsMr. James WilsonMr. David WilsonMr. Andrew WiltMrs. Sydney WisselDr. Jaime Yáñez Peña,     In Honor of la dignidad y la libertidad PeruanaMr. Aaron Yeargan

     

    Thursday, September 30 Mr. Richard AlbarinoAldo AlesiiMr. Bryan AmadorMr. Norman E. Andrews,     In Memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. Ryan ArnoldMr. Daniel AronsonMr. Ben AycriggMr. Don BabnewMr. Bill BaergMr. Justin BakerMr. Theodore BakerMr. Eric BauerMr. Julio BaylacMs. Lisa BellRena Ben-AvrahamMr. Dale BensonMrs. Mary BettinsonMr. Heinz BitterliMr. John BooneMr. Jeff BowmanMr. Paul W. BramerMr. Patrick BrannanMr. Gary BrogochDr. David BrunellMr. Jay BurtonMr. Bobby CampbellMr. Gregory CarrMr. David CatesMr. Alberto Luigi CesarettiMrs. Kristy ChandlerMr. Gregory CitarellaMr. Duane CochranMr. Mark ColemanMr. Lawrence ColucciDr. Pearl CompaanMr. Dominic CompozMr. and Mrs. Michael E. Coughlin,     In Memory of Bernard CoughlinMr. Victor CoxMr. Richard CunniffMs. Natalie Danelishen,In Memory of Leo BeaneMr. Michael DarnellMr. Gerald P. DaveyMr. Robert DaveyMr. Alfred R. DavieMr. Alan DavisMr. Dennis De FordDr. Ovidio De LeonMr. John DePasqualeMr. Michael DietrichMr. Lawrence DixonMr. Eugene DoroshMr. Brian DoyleMr. Richard A. DrosslerMr. Richard C. Duell, lllMr. Donald E. DuffAnonymous,     In Honor of David GordonMr. Kenneth DunnMr. James EavesAnonymousMr. Craig EvansAnonymousMr. Gabriel FancherMr. Shawn FedinatzMr. Kyle FennerMs. Mary Lynn FerkalukMr. David FitzgeraldMr. Charles FlynnMr. Brock FlynnMr. Alan ForresterMs. Colette FosterMr. Trent FowlerMr. Dick FriedenMr. David GarciaMr. Alan GardnerMr. Joe GarlockMr. Eric GlennMr. John GoodMr. Michael GoodmanMr. Robert GrahamMr. Matthew GrajewskiMr. Ron GreenhoughMr. John G. GrossMr. Richard GullottiMr. James R. HartjeMr. Paul HaugenMr. Patrick HepnerMr. Gregory HigleyMr. Jeffrey HillMr. Rollin HilliardMr. Nathan HinelineRachal HislerMr. Clyde HughesMr. Pavel IlcikMr. Zachary IngersollMr. Daniel A. JeffreMr. Kevin JenkinsMr. Donald A. JessMs. Elizabeth JohnsonAnonymousArrash KamranMr. David KeaheyMr. Brian KeaneMr. Robert KeithMr. Joseph KingMr. Kevin KnappMr. Jiri KneslMr. Alexandros KonstantinidisMr. Nathan KreiderMr. Matthew W. Krogdahl,In Memory of Percy and Bettina GreavesMr. David LandwehrMr. Evan Larson,     In Memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. Mark LautmanMr. Branndon LawsonMr. Carsten Lehn Toft,     In Honor of MisesMr. Mathew LloydSy LuuMr. Rick MaddrenRoleigh MartinMrs. Margaret MassariMr. Charles McCagheyMr. and Mrs. Thomas McCrary, Jr.Mr. Alec McDowellMr. Eugene McGowanMs. Leeann L. MeansMr. Charles MercerMr. John MillerMs. Kathryn MillerMr. Andres Minondo,     In Memory of Luis SamayoaMr. Robert Monteath-WilsonMr. Brandon MuellerWael MuslehMr. Travis NorthwayProf. Aleksandar NovakovicMr. Juan OlaecheaMr. Eric OlsonPat PalmerBorjan PanovskiMr. David PetersMs. Pamela PhillipsAnonymous,     In Memory of Ronald S. HertzMr. Lionel PlataMr. Carlos PonceMr. Vladimir PopovicMr. Jason RandolphMr. Brian RaphaelKerri ReinboldMr. Will ReishmanMr. Robert ReynoldsMs. Marcia RichardsonMr. James RicksMr. Raymond H. RondeauMr. Graham RowanMr. Robert L.M. RussellMr. Karl RydenMr. Steven SadlerMr. Mike SalzaMr. Christopher SauerweinMr. Jeffrey ScamponeMr. Michael ScarbroughMr. Michael SchedlerMr. William Schelinski,     In Honor of Ronald L. WieckMr. Nick SchiefenMr. Ron SilvaMs. Carroll SimpsonMr. Ian SinclairMr. Teemu SintonenMr. Dennis SipsyMr. Riley SizeloveMr. Robert SmithMr. Erik SmittMrs. Connie SnipesMs. Cathleen SpearsMr. Daniel C. SteeleMs. Suzanne StephanKameron StevensonMr. Peter StipanovichMr. Peter StollmackMr. Michael TedescoSam TeelMr. Robert Thomson,     In Honor of all who have died in the fight for freedomThrasher IP Law, PCMs. Kaitlin TierneyMr. Christian TolinoMr. Jim TuckerMr. Emilio Turbay GarcíaMr. Christopher Twomey,     In Honor of Ludwig von MisesMr. Christopher P. ValleMr. Adrian van den EndenMr. Tim Van HussMr. William VetterMr. Alexander VossMr. Lawrence WaldmanMr. Doug WhiteMr. James WildeMiss Kerri Ellen WilderMs. Arianna WilkersonMr. Michael R. WilsonMr. Andrew WilsonMr. Duke WilwaycoMr. Riley WipfMr. PG Wist     Mr. Micheal J. Wyatt, In Honor of John D. WyattMr. George YoungMr. Matt Zimmer

     

    Wednesday, September 29 Mr. Peter AdamsMr. Norman E. Andrews,     In Memory of Ludwig von MisesAnonymousMr. Florin-Paul ArmeneanMr. Chris BeachlerMr. Chris BennettMrs. Nikolina Bilić PoljanićMr. Steven BirchfieldMr. Daniel BjorndahlMr. Gregory BoschMr. Nick BrennfoerderMr. William BrownMs. Brenda BrowningMr. Michael Brusser,      In Honor of Thomas SowellMr. Charles C. Burridge,      In Honor of Lew RockwellMr. Tom CairnsMr. David CalhounMr. Anthony CarmonaMr. Carl ChambersMr. James ChanceyMr. Luke ChenMr. Michael ChristiansenMr. Pierre CôtéMiss Melissa Crockett,      In Honor of Donald J. Trump, the most gifted natural economist in the history of the United States of America.Ms. Kristine A. CrossMr. Bradley CrumMr. Rodney DavenportLini Dedo,      In Memory of баба ми ЕвдокияAnonymousMr. Dan Derby, IIIMr. Michael DiamondP. DickinsonMr. Neal DowlingMr. Craig A. DownsMr. Matthew DrakeMr. Scott DunstanMs. Faith ElliottMr. Grier EllisMr. Randy Enderle,      In Memory of Gail D. VillariMs. Elise EntzenbergerMr. John FisherMr. Wayne FordMrs. Tamara GoforthMr. Robert GonzalesMr. Santiago GonzalezMs. Diana GreigMr. Gene GryzieckiMr. Benjamin HainesMr. Christopher M. HalfenMr. Hal Hamilton, Jr.Mr. Nicholas HankoffMs. Rosalind HarbinMr. Ralf HeinAnonymousMr. Lars HellmanMr. Mikal HendeeMr. Caleb HerodMr. Mike Hogan,     In Memory of Terry HoganJay HuchowskiMr. Adam JenningsMr. David JohnstoneMr. John V. Jones, Jr., PhD, LPC-SMr. Justin JozokosMr. Justin KastenMr. Justin KeeneyMr. Hugh KendrickMr. Christos KolovosMr. Christo KostovMr. Sanjay KothariMs. Debbie Lai,     In Honor of our Almighty God’s memory!Mr. Russell V. LambertiDr. Paul LeslieMs. Heather LockhartAnonymousMr. Mark MacheyMr. Malcolm MackMr. Miguel MalagonMr. Joseph Matarese,     In Memory of Teresa MatareseMr. Jeff McCallMr. Jon McDonaldDonnell McAuliffeMr. Athel W. Miller, IIMr. George Miller-DavisMr. Eric MingeeMr. Daniel Muehl-MillerMr. Robert MüllerMr. John MurrayAnonymousMr. Mohammad NaumanMr. Hoang Duc NguyenMs. Wanjiru NjoyaMr. Patrick O'DonnellMr. Michael O'NeillMr. Mikko OjanenJaime OrtizMr. Norm PierceMr. Rodney PilbrowMr. Daniel PlattMr. Paul PrestonMr. Jonathan RasoDr. Michael RawMr. Attila RebakMr. Tim ReganMs. Katherine ReignerMr. Robert RenkMr. Derek RethmanMr. Anthony RicciardiMs. Sarah RichardsJoelle RichardsonMr. Pierre RobertMs. Jane Robinson,     In Honor of G. Edward Griffin – Happy Birthday!Mr. John B. RoemerMs. Ann RohanMr. Ryan RosenkingMr. Frederic Rousseau,     In Honor of the Mises InstituteMr. Thomas Ruane,     In Memory of Michael L. Ruane, MDMr. Aaron RushingDr. George SaundersMr. Jeffrey ScamponeAnonymousMr. David SchwendingerMr. Joseph SeawellMr. Stephen SebastianMs. Mary SherryMr. Michael SimonMr. Derek SimpsonMr. John SlayMr. Dan SlickerMr. Timothy SmithMr. Noah SmithMr. James SondgerothKees SpaanMr. William SpringerMs. Claudia StaplesMr. Joseph StarnesMr. John TateMr. Anthony TiliacosMr. Carlos Tirado AngelMr. Gregory ToddMr. Jeff TunstallMs. Wendy VanCleve,     In Honor of Kurt FullerMr. Alex VanderwellMr. Michael WatsonMr. Alan WeierMs. Christina WelchMs. Gina Wells,     In Honor of Ludwig von Mises birthdayMr. Robert WemerMr. Marcin WielochMrs. Lupita A. WiggansMr. John WilliamsMr. Shawn YeagerMr. Herbert Yussim

     

    Tuesday, September 28 Mr. Carlos AdaroMr. Dallas AdolphsenMr. Michael AyresMr. Armando AzpuruaParrish BegnaudMr. John BlaineyDr. Walter E. Block,     In Memory of Murray RothbardMr. Dave BowersMr. Douglas CableMr. Robert CaldwellMr. Bobby CampbellMr. James CarlyleMs. Melissa CarrollMr. Derek CarterMr. Brad CliffordMr. Ethan CoeMr. Gary CookMr. Reginald Cook,     In Memory of military veteransMr. Edgar CrossmanMr. Frank CrowtherMr. Spencer CuretonMr. Crisanto DelgadoMr. Eric DurtcheMr. Mark EcklerMr. Richard EdmistenMr. Harry Elliott,     In Memory of Ayn RandMr. David EvansJaime Fernandez DelgadoMs. Karen Fitzgerald,     In Honor of Dr. Thomas SowellMr. Travis FrydenlundMr. Jorge Gadea AlfaroDr. Dennis P. GilmanMs. Lynnette HansmannMr. Geoff HarpurMrs. Ellen HathawayMr. Gordon ImrothMr. Dan Johnson and Ms. Randee LaskewitzMr. Richard JohnstonMr. Paulo Jorge PereiraMr. Rudy KaethlerMr. John KallielMr. Jason KellyMr. Michael KingPepijn KnetschMr. Greg LefflerMs. Carol MarangoniMr. Marc MayfieldAnonymousMs. Carrie McPhersonMr. Dale MillerMr. Joe MoracaMr. Vernon MoretMr. David MuellerMr. Benjamin NadelsteinAnonymousMr. Gregg ObbinkMr. Michael PattersonMr. Neal PhenesMr. Peter PintoMs. Roberta Privette,     In Memory of Mary ArgerosMr. John PruittMr. Michael ReddSascha RichertMr. Andre RIvetMr. Clark RollinsMr. Gabe L. RoyerYahya Saleem-BeyMr. Edward ScherrerMr. Myles ShivesMr. John SotirakisMr. Bill StampMr. David StefanMrs. Pamela StoutMr. Carlos Tapang,     In Memory of Crisostomo TapangMr. Stephen TempleMr. Andrew TomashaskaMr. Alan TownsonMr. Scott P. TreaseMr. Edward TuttleMr. R. David Van TreurenMr. Gregory VisscherMr. Fabian von Schilcher,     In Honor of Satoshi NakamotoMr. Howard WallaceMr. Vern WestgateMr. Newton WhiteMr. John Williams,     In Honor of all the countless millions who have died under the boot of communismMs. Jennifer WisnoffMr. Elmer A. Wright,     In Memory of Grand ChildrenMr. Viktor YoshimuraMr. Pedro Zapata Gil

     

    Monday, September 27 Mr. Abdelhamid AbdouMr. Meldon AchesonMr. John AdlerDr. Richard Adler,     In Memory of Nancy AdlerMr. Robert AdrianMr. and Mrs. J. Ryan AlfordMr. Leandro Alonzo BurguenoMr. Christian Alvarez,     In Honor of all the libertarian people that are involved in the ideas battle in LatinoamericaAnonymousMr. Michael ArchieMr. Richard Armstrong,     In Memory of Zechariah FarrEdgard BaqueiroMr. Durwood BarronDon BarzykDr. Jeremy BellMr. Davis Bennett,     In Honor of Dr. Ron PaulMr. Thomas BertrandAnonymousMr. Stuart BeverleyMr. Dennis M. BlairMr. Michael BlevinsMr. Jeremy M. BolesMr. Michael BonenbergerGosse BoumaMr. Melvin BrandlMr. Ryan BreenMr. Keith BrilhartMr. Caleb BrownMr. Scott BurkhardtMr. Michael BurkhartMr. Brian BurleyMr. Matthew J. CannonMr. Scott CarlMr. Sammy CartagenaMark CasamentoBobby CatheyMr. Johnny ChinMr. Alex CombsMr. Robert CourserMr. Marc DAngeloRobin DeaMr. Ethan DemilioMr. Jose De SouzaNikola DimitrovMr. Aleksandar DjuricicMs. Maureen Dowst, CPA, PLLCMr. Kent DrinkwaterAnonymousMr. Caleb EarlMr. Bryce EickholtErol EraOr EzraMr. Tom FachanMr. Donald FannonMr. Thomas FelixMr. Justin FischerMr. Tony FulgenziMr. Frank GalushaMr. Aron GahaganMr. Allen GindlerAnonymousMr. David GleasonMr. Robert GordonDr. Marvin GrahamMs. Charlotte Kay GrahamMs. Elizabeth GravelyMr. John GriecoMr. Tyler GrossmanMr. Matthew GunterMr. Luis Gustavo FelippiMr. Randall HansenMr. R. Reid HansonMr. Sheldon HayerMr. Logan HazanMr. Jack HendersonMs. Amandah Hendricks,     In Memory of FreedomMr. Joseph HenningerMr. Daniel HerltMr. Terrill HerringMr. James HickeyMr. Philip HillMr. Chris HindmarchMr. Nathan HinesRW HobertMr. Stephen HolohanMr. Daniel HolwayMr. Timothy HotchkissMr. Hal HowertonMr. Curtis M. HowlandMr. Bill HoyerMr. Mark HunterMr. Jeffrey JacobiMr. Bob JonesDorian JonesMr. Jeremy JonesMr. Peter J. KaliskyMr. Charles KapelaMr. Brandon KarpelesMrs. Marnie KerrisonDr. Ricardo Almeida KilsonMr. Thomas KirwanMr. Jacob KlaserAnton KovalenkoMr. Kenneth KuhnMr. John H. LandMr. Shawn LazarDr. Nicolau Leal Werneck,     In Honor of the central-planners out thereMr. Andrew LeaverMr. Kevin LeCureuxMr. Jean LesperanceMr. Jared Lindquist,     In Honor of Hoppean.orgThiago LoMr. Richard LodatoMr. Matthew LorenceMr. Jacob LovellZoran LowMr. Michael LukeDimitrios LypourlisMr. Aaron MaciasMrs. Caroline MacriBenedict MaliakkalMr. William MalisMr. Gabriel MarinMr. Kris P. MarinMr. Neal MarstonMr. John MasonMr. Samuel MatthewsMr. Roy McCollumMr. James E. McCullenZeke MckeeMr. Frank McLeanAnonymousMarco MessinaMs. Susan MeyersMr. Todd MillerMr. Zach MillsMs. Gail MitchellMr. Samuel A. MitchellMr. Michael MilovancevMr. Mark MorettiMr. Jack MosesMr. Richard MuldoonDr. James W. MulhollandDr. Lyle MullerMs. Helen NardiMr. Connor ObrienBoo O’ConnerMr. Marcus OmlinMr. Robert OnderMr. Michael PageMr. John W. PanchukMr. Nilo PascoalotoMr. Enrique Pascual ManzanoMr. Alvin PlummerMr. Joshua PolkMr. James PottsMs. Margareta RaducanMr. Bruno RaphenonMr. Richard ReevesMr. Kurt RescharMs. Susanna ReynoldsIvo RibeiroMr. James RobinsonMr. Richard RossMr. David RoyleQuentin SalleyMr. Rajiv SarafMr. James SawyerMr. Joshua SchubertMr. Pete SecorMs. Julie Seiffert JastoMs. Karen SelickMr. Mikhail Serfontein,     In Honor of Jurie and Uta SerfonteinJesse ShattuckMr. Eduard SherstnevHelder Simoes,In Honor of Nuno NevesMr. Andrew SmithHochiu SoMs. Deborah SolomonMr. Donald SolowAJ TyvandMr. Byron L. StoeserMr. Allen Stokes,     In Honor of Ludwig von MisesMr. David Stroh, JD,     In Memory of Edwin J. StrohMr. Laron TamayeRoxane TeleshaMr. Michael ThomasMr. Thomas Timpone,     In Honor of John AdamsMr. Joseph TorsielloMr. Michael TownsendRoman TraberMr. Aaron TuttleMr. Steve Tuttle,     In Memory of Ed LampittMr. Hank Van GasseltMr. Lionel VasquezMr. Ian VigusMr. Nicholas WalkerMr. Jason Watson,     In Honor of Michael Malice and Tom WoodsMr. David WengerMr. Ronald L. WestMr. Christopher WestleyMr. Todd WilliamsMr. Joe WithrowMs. Elaine WoodriffMr. Roger WoodwardDC WornockMr. Christopher C. WrenMr. Jeffrey A. YerkesMr. David ZientaraMr. Robert Zumwalt

     

    All donors will be listed on our home page this week. Recurring donors of $5 or more, or one-time donors of $60 or more, will receive a free copy of The Middle of the Road Leads to Socialism by Ludwig von Mises.

    Mises Wire
    enOctober 03, 2021

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    Thanks to Our Fall Campaign Donors

    "Thank you!" to the generous supporters, below, who donated to our Fall Campaign. The best people in the world support the Mises Institute. Will you join them?

    The goal of our Fall Campaign is simple—to increase our Membership and our influence. Please take time to donate TODAY.

     

    Saturday, October 3 Mr. Kelly BeanMr. Chris BecraftViera BibrDr. Chad BigonyMr. Heinz BitterliMr. John BlaineyDr. Walter E. Block,in honor of MurrayMr. Yann BongiovanniMr. Kristopher BorerMr. William C. Brennan,memory Kraig McKownMs. Rebecca BrewingtonMr. Gary BrogochMr. Petter BrolinMr. Michael BrusserMr. Steven BuerkleMr. Scott BullardMr. Scott BurkhardtMr. Michael BurksFrans Buzek and Liliana Mateus AldanaMr. Robert Calabro,    in memory of deceased members of the Calabro and Iannuzzo familiesMr. Thomas CaldwellMr. David CarlsonMr. Wayne ChapeskieMr. Alec ChevalierMr. Johnny ChinBogdan CholakovMs. Linda ChynowethGordon P. Clark, MDMr. William Colburn,    in honor Dr. Ron PaulMr. Fabrizio ComperMr. Lynn ConeMr. Richard F. ConwayMs. Cheryle CooperMr. Matthew CoppedgeMr. Shane CoulesMs. Kristine A. CrossMr. David CrouchAnonymousMr. Steven De Klerck,    in memory of Ludwig von MisesMs. Jane DelgerDr. Kenneth DeLongMs. Jennifer DenBleykerMr. Paul J. DietrichDr. Thomas J. DiLorenzoMr. Lawrence DixonMr. Tom DouglasMr. Igor DrabMr. Andrej DrapalMr. Elias EconomouMr. Brenton ElisbergMr. Adam FavaroMr. Alan FanningMr. Joseph D. FeiferMr. Joe FertittaMs. Eileen Findlay,    in memory of Peter Burke FindlayMs. Sandra FormanczykMr. André FortinMr. and Mrs. James E. FosterMr. C. Scott FreemanMr. Josef FrendreisMr. Lee FridayMr. William FullerMr. David GallerMs. Carol GarciaMr. Gary T. GeddensMr. Mark GilmoreMr. Stephen GinnettiMr. Artem Glushchuk,    in memory of FreedomMrs. Tamara GoforthMs. Janice GottliebMr. Chester GranardMr. Peter GrigorMr. Richard GrimesMrs. Joan GrindelMr. Matt GrubbsMr. Tommy GustMr. Christopher Hammond,    in memory of Gerald E. Hammond, MDMr. Ethan HammondsMr. Hill HamptonWou Sang HanMr. Geoff HarpurMr. Richard G. Hartman,    in memory of LaVerne and Joyce HartmanOtto HavelMr. James Hayman,    in honor of Tom WoodsMr. Kevin HedgesAnonymousMr. Dan HendershotMr. Shane M. HendrenMr. Luke HenkeniusMr. Sebastian Hernandez CarmonaMr. John HicksMs. Rosemary HolmMrs. Tara HopwoodMr. Timothy HotchkissAnonymousMr. James A. Howe,    in honor of MurrayMr. Aaron HowellMr. Marvin HughesMr. Richard Humphrey, III,    in honor of Dr. Randall HolcombeMr. Matthew ItzoMr. Bruce JalaMr. David JonesMr. John KaschMr. Marcel KepplerMs. Karen Killinger-HumesMr. Dylan KizyMr. Paul KlarenbergMr. Kevin KnappMr. John KnoxDr. Rudolph KohnMr. William KolpaskyMr. Greg KuruvillaMr. Rick LahrsonMr. Matt LanterMr. Nathan LantsMr. James LazearMr. Glenn LeeMr. Andrew LeeMr. Yevgen Lemberg,    in memory of Natalia LinetskayaMyra LewinLivia LillMr. Jeff LindsayMr. Barry LinetskyMr. Tim LipusMr. Paul LockmanMr. Thomas LonerganMr. Phillip LuchettaMr. John LummusMr. Mark MarekMr. Alexander MarkesinisMr. James MartinMr. Jorge MateoMr. Warren MatthewsMr. John McCartyMr. Mark McGrath,    in memory of MajGen Smedley D. Butler, USMCMr. James McKibbinMs. Suzanne McMaken,in honor of Pauline and Jesse GalindoMr. Caleb McmillenMr. Doug McNabbMs. Rebecca McNameeAli MecklaiMr. Charles A. MertesMs. Kathryn MillerMr. Reuben MillerMr. David MitchellMs. Vickie MoehlmanMr. Charles L. MorrealeArne and Jonalee MortensenMr. Arthur NationMr. Alexander NazarenkoMr. John NelsonMiss Ruxandra NistorescuMs. Wanjiru NjoyaMr. James Norman, Jr.Mr. and Mrs. Kevin A. NorthMr. Don NorthamMr. Brian OdonoghueMr. Jerry O'NeilMr. Michael OrtonMr. Rick O'SteenMr. Allen OvereemMs. Nicole PapakostasMr. Allen Pegues,    in memory of James Cary Pegues, Jr.Mr. Justin PerryMr. John PhelanMr. Rodney PilbrowMr. David PlanchardWessel PorschenMr. Jacob PorterDr. and Mrs. Francis M. Powers, Jr.Mr. Robert PrellAnonymousMiss Kelly QuesenberryMr. Saul RackauskasMr. Richard Reese, IIIMr. Will ReishmanAnonymousMr. Richard RochelleMs. Rosemarie RotellaMs. Rita RussellMr. Christopher RymanMr. Al SadaghianiMr. Gerard SalamoneDr. Steven SandersMr. Paul SantucciDavid and Elaine SarosiMr. Bernard P. ScheurleMr. Jack SchlichtingMr. Robert SchwanbeckMr. Charles SebrellDiann Shook-CrenshawMr. Nikiforos SkoumasDr. H. Leland Smith,    in memory of Dr. Hans SennholzMr. Isaac SmithMr. Frank SmithMr. Jay SmithDr. James SpeightsMr. David StanowskiMr. Timothy E. StevensMr. Robert J. StewartMr. Michael StewartMr. James SummersMr. Robert SzymaszczykMr. Trent N. TalbertMr. Ryan TaylorMr. James TaylorMr. John TeitenbergMr. Charles Tronolone,    in honor of Lew Rockwell and Dr. Ron PaulMr. Richard UbertoGoran UgrinoskiMr. Don Van GorpMr. Mitchell A. VanyaMr. Paul C. VerdereseMr. William VetterMr. Robert A. VincentMr. Michael VliesMr. Robert VogelMr. Edward WalterMr. Jack WellsNatalie and Dustin WenzMr. Ronald WestMr. Andrew WestheadMr. Benjamin WiegoldAnonymousMrs. Lupita A. WiggansMr. Kenneth WilcoxMr. Edward WilkesMr. Jon WilliamsMr. James WittesMr. Michael G. Wood,    in memory of Yami Frances WoodMr. Larry N. Woods,    in memory of Robert LeFevreZongxiong Ye

     

    Friday, October 2 Mr. Richard AlbarinoMr. Arthur E. AlbinJohn F. Ambrose, MDMr. Michael BaerresenMs. Alexandra Ballantine,    in honor of Jacob HornbergerMr. Bruce BarberaMr. Brad BarsnessMr. Alex BassoMr. Meridan BennettMr. Andrew BerselliLeslie Blouin,    in honor of Murray RothbardMr. Eddie BlueMr. Martin BlythMr. Walter Bradley,    in memory of my father, Walter T. Bradley, Jr.Mr. Daniel BradyMr. Nicolaas BruijnMr. Andrei G. BucurMr. Charles C. BurridgeMr. John BusenitzMr. Mauricio CanedoMr. Juan Cano DiazMr. Yuk Ming CheungAnonymousMr. Brandon CillaMr. Edward ClarkMr. Richard ClarkeMr. Mark ColemanMr. Harry CollisMs. Susan CortesMr. Donald K. CowlesMr. Eric CrowleyMs. Melissa D'ArcheMs. Margaret A. DaggsMr. Andrew DiabMr. Bill DonabedianMr. Daniel DonovanMr. Constantin DragomirovMr. David DustinMr. Bill DyerMr. Jerry EdwardsMrs. Courtenay EllisonMr. Clint EtzelMr. Bob EvansMr. Katherine FarleyMr. Franklin Fiedler,    in memory of Juanees RossMs. Sandra Filosof-SchipperMr. Armando FloresMr. Thomas FordMr. Steven ForresterMr. Martin C. FoxMr. Michael GaffneyMr. Pedro GaivaoMr. Robert Garretson,    in honor of Christian GarretsonDr. Teresa GasallaDr. Marvin GrahamMr. Jonathan GuntherMr. Mark HannaMr. Samuel HarkinMs. Lucy HarrisonMadison HartMr. David HauensteinMr. Bret HayesMr. Jack HendersonMr. Paul HerrickRobert Heuermann, M.D.Janez HlebanjaMr. Axel HoebekeMs. Melanie HolzmanMr. Michael Houze,in memory of David JacksonMr. Richard HutchingsMr. Raymond IsbellMr. Daniel A. JeffreMr. Johnathan JenkinsMr. Peter L. Johnson,    in honor of Robert Murphy, Israel Kirzner, and Gerald O’DriscollMr. Dan KellyMr. Don KilcoyneMr. Garett KleinschmidtMr. Eric KlierVasko KohlmayerMr. Francis KuhlmanMr. Steven La Bella,    in loving memory of R. Nelson NashMr. Russell V. Lamberti,    in honor of Ludwig von MisesMs. Candace LamoreeMs. Vicki LamppinMr. John H. LandKerri LandisHenri Le BihanMr. Dewey LevieMr. Carl LöwegrenDr. Joshua Malay,    in memory of Odne StokkaMr. Gabriel Marin,    in honor of Dr. Ron PaulMr. Frank MartinMr. Sladan MastilovicMr. Clinton McGrathMr. Michael J. McKayMr. Kent McKeeMr. James McKibbinMr. Edward MelanMr. Michael MillerAnonymousMr. Reuben MillerMr. Aleksandar MojovicMr. Vladimir MorgensternMr. Eric MorrisMr. Brian C. MulliganAnonymousMr. Matan NatansonTeri NewhallMs. Alison NicholsMr. Micha NiskinMr. John OglesbyMr. Aaron OlsonMr. Antonio Ortega AlbonicoTalat OzyagcilarMr. Donald PadalisDr. Pedro Alfredo PerezDr. and Mrs. Philip PiaseckiMr. Charles PickmanMr. James PillionMr. John R. PorterMr. Jordi PosthumusMr. Aaron PrinceMr. Alexander ProffittMr. Kevin PursleyMr. Andrew QuinnMr. Richard RandallMr. Daniel ReindersMr. Jose ReveloMr. Jon RobertMr. Ian RossiDr. Peter RoweMs. Susan RushMr. John E. RushingMr. David W. SandersMr. Larry SchmerbeckMr. Benjamin SchmittMr. Allan SelbyMr. Christopher SeyfertMr. Jesse ShattuckMr. Jeffrey Shaw,    in memory of Karl HessMr. Eduard SherstnevMr. Bob SimeralMr. Michael SimonMr. and Mrs. Thomas W. SingletonMr. Walter SmithMr. George F. Smith,    in honor of Preston Scott NicholsMr. Richard SobotaMr. David StallsmithMs. Claudia StaplesMr. Sebastian-Oliver SternAnonymousMr. Gregory StrebelMr. Adam SylvesterMr. Seth ThompsonMr. David Tubbs,    in memory of Donald TubbsAnonymousAlex VerlindenMr. Michael Von HattenMr. Grover WallsMr. Michael Waters,    in memory of Tom SparksMr. Jack WellsMr. Robert WemerMr. Richard WestrupMr. Marcin WielochMr. Stephen WindahlMr. Frank WiseMr. PG WistMr. Norris WoodMr. Michael WoodsJungho YooMr. Thomas Young,    in memory of R. Nelson NashMr. Warren Y. Zeger,    in honor of Prof. Sylvester Petro

     

    Wednesday, September 30 Mr. Mariano BasMr. Julio BaylacMr. Arnes BegicMr. Ron BertiMs. Jacqueline BlackMr. Christopher BondMs. Judith BoveMr. Paul BowenMr. Paul BraccoMr. Richard BradtMr. Joseph BrittonMr. Edmund BrooksMr. Joseph Buczek,    in honor of Dr. Ron PaulPer and Susanne BylundDr. Athanasios Chymis,    in memory of Demetrius Kolias, PhDMr. John CiccotelliMr. Eugene ColliganMs. Teresa L. CosperMr. Trevor DaherSamir DeebMr. Javan DeGraffMr. Nikolaas de JongDr. Adolfo De UbietaDr. Ljubomir DimitrovskiMr. Thomas DoughertyAnonymousMr. Minh DuongMr. Geoff DurhamMr. Omar ElkhatibMr. Justin EndertonMs. Nina ErdmannMr. Norman FaccoMr. James FedakoMr. Bryant FisherMs. Sheila GallagherMr. Philip GarlandMr. John GermanyTy GiesemannMr. Gregory GordonAnonymousMr. Ryan HartMr. Daniel HerltDr. and Mrs. James M. HerringTerry HuffmanCurran HydeMr. John JordanMr. Kyle KeeganMr. Peter KeoughMr. Ricardo KilsonMr. William KittelsonMr. Alexandros KonstantinidisMr. Lawrence KuhlmanMr. Brent KupferMr. Jeremy LeenknechtMr. Thomas LevinsMr. Carl LocignoMr. Thomas LonerganHarmon Lowman, IIIMr. Christopher Manning,    in honor of Dr. Ron PaulDr. Karl MaritatoMr. Steve MarriottMr. Elias MassartMr. William MielochMr. Kevin MileyMr. Steve MillerMr. David MisiscoMr. Edwin MorilloMr. Ryan NadeauMr. Jon NallMr. James O'BrienMr. James ObermeyerMr. Christopher OhnstadMr. Glenn ParishMr. Amit Reuveni,    in honor of Ohad OsterreicherMr. Rodolfo RoballosMr. Mark SchmielMr. Ryan SearfoorceMr. Matthew SenfieldMr. James Michael Smith,    in honor of Dr. Ron PaulMr. Bernhard W. StalzerDanielle StanleyMr. David SteuberAnonymousMr. Gregory StrzempekMr. Alan SwopeMr. James TaylorMr. Stephen TempleMr. Daniel TeskeMr. Robert TokarzMr. John B. TrolingerMr. Patrick Underwood, Jr.Mr. Ger van GilsMr. David Van SlyckMr. Thomas VarnadoMs. Anna VinogradovaMr. Brad WastlerMr. Austin WaungMr. Bruce WeddendorfMr. Christopher WeimannMr. Lee O. Welter,    in memory of Douglas Arthur “Art” TumaMr. Dean WilsonMr. Robert WimsattMr. Michael WithrowMs. Elaine WoodriffMr. David Zientara

     

    Tuesday, September 29 Mr. Abdelhamid AbdouMr. Adnan Al-Abbar,   in honor of Dr. Haidar KhajahCiro AndradeMr. Donald ArmstrongMr. Igor AyalaDr. J. Duncan BerryMr. Philip BoggsMr. Daryl BortzMr. Yani BrankovMr. Donald Burger,   In honor of Ludwig von MisesMs. Dorothea BurstynMr. Carroll BusherMr. Dennis M. CampbellMr. James CarlyleMr. Ricky CarneyMr. Russell CaseySheryl CastelloMr. Bobby CatheyMr. Luke Ciardi,   in honor of Ludwig von MisesMs. Victoria ClickMr. Thomas Colella,   in memory of Al ColellaMr. Kevin CourtneyMr. Harry CoxMr. Stephen DavidsonMr. Peter denDulkMr. Matthew DeNicolaMr. Frank Dieterich,   in memory of Murray N. RothbardMr. Robert F. Dillman, Jr.Ms. Farrah DomekaMr. Mike Dumitriu,   in honor of Hans Hermann HoppeMr. Ian DunlapMr. Mark EcklerMr. Harry ElliottMr. Eric EnglundMr. J. Guillermo Figueroa,    in memory of Joseph KeckeissenMr. Jan M. Fijor,   in memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. Tony FulgenziMr. J. Bruce Gabriel,   in memory of Ludwig von MisesMr. Dennis GarrardMr. Patrick GasmenMr. Frank GrahamMr. Gene GryzieckiMr. William HanekampMr. Sheldon HayerMr. Sean Hernandez,   in honor of Tank ManMs. Katherine HigginsMr. Jeffrey HillMr. Daniel HolwayMr. Justin HolzerMr. Troy HudsonMr. Douglas HunterMr. Gregg HunterMr. Jay JacksonMr. Nik JazbinsekMr. Hrvoje Jelić,   in memory of Olga JelićMr. Franklin KellerMr. Ben KnowlesMr. Joe KosterichMr. Nathan KreiderMr. David KushMr. Barron LataquinMr. Junior Leslie,   in honor of Ludwig von MisesMr. Mike Lev,   in memory of YK ALMr. Charles LewisMr. Phillip L. LindseyMr. John LinskeyMr. Michael W. MaceMr. J. Stuart MacLeanMr. Attila MadarasCarole MannyMr. Efthimis Maramis,   in memory of Murray Newton RothbardMr. Anthony MarescoDr. Stephen MarmerMr. Neal MarstonLee MbuguaMr. Boone McBrideMr. John McCartyMr. Brett McClain,   in memory of Perry McClainMr. Kary McFaddenMs. Catherine E. MellorMaurizzio MenneaMr. Ralph Miller,   in memory of Ralph LoydMr. George Miller-DavisMr. Mark MoersenMrs. Jane Moffitt,   in memory of Edward L. MoffittMr. Jack MosesMs. Maria Gabriela MradMr. Edward MurrayDr. Patrick NewmanMr. Ohad OsterreicherMr. Steven OswaldMr. William J. OttMr. Ralph PascualyMr. Dennis Pavick,   in memory of Melinda and Caroline CassidyMs. Signa PendegraftMr. Alvin PlummerMr. Rich PrestonMr. Tsvetalin RadevMr. James RadtkeChonzom RapgayDr. David J. RappMr. Jonathan RasoDr. John J. RayDr. Matthew ReverMr. Brendan RiceMiss Gyneth G. RichardsMr. Vincent RichardsonMr. Brett RiggsMs. Ann RohanMr. Scott RossMr. William RusherNemrod SaldanasLourdes SalvadorMr. Michael Schinstock,   in memory of Jack SchinstockMr. Mike SchmidMr. David SchwendingerMr. Rajiv ShahRic StejbachMr. K.G. StephensMr. Peter StipanovichMs. Susan Stoppkotte,   in memory of Craig WeeksMs. Molly StryjewskiMs. Nicole TateMr. Jonathan ThompsonMr. Stephen VickeryMr. R. Jeffrey White,   in honor of Ronald R. WhiteMr. Chris WilsonMr. Michael R. WilsonMr. Joseph Withrow,   in honor of Isaiah JosephMr. Bennett WoodwardMs. Emily WoofendenMr. Robert Zumwalt

     

    Monday, September 28 Ms. Alyssa BaileyMr. Andrius BalandisDr. Francis Xavier Bardavío AraMr. Thomas BertrandMr. Randy BleyerMr. Mark BloomMr. Randy BoringMr. Boris BorissovAnonymousMr. Charles BorregoMr. Trevor BrownMr. Richard BrowningMr. Thomas J. BurlingameMr. Richard CausleyMr. Paul CerinoMr. Juan Carlos CervelleraHong ChenMr. Bruno Cormouls-HoulèsMr. Everett DavisMr. Dennis De FordMr. and Mrs. Allen DempsterDr. Atanu DeyMr. Paul DohertyMr. Eugene DoroshMr. Kent DrinkwaterMr. Romain DurandMr. Joshua EnderleMr. Dirk EnkMr. Mike EverettMr. Bart FrazierMr. Pedro GaivaoMr. Robert GaleMr. Surajit GoswamiMr. Robert HartnettMr. Stanley HeardMr. Adam HeinrichMr. Nathan HinesMr. François HodlerAnonymousMr. Andreas Huebner and    Mrs. Maria Jose Silva RomanMr. Paul IsherwoodMr. Michael ItzoMr. Daniel A. JeffreDr. Porter JenkinsMr. Guojie JiaMr. Brian JohnsonDr. James JusticeMr. Peter J. KaliskyMs. Kaye KamonMr. Kevin KellMr. Cory KleinMr. Jim KnowlerBernard and Joan KoetherMr. Greg KrabbenhoftMr. Alex KulikowskiDr. Dennis KulondaMr. Matthew LaRocheMr. Jon LawrenceMr. Charles LebedaDr. Paul LeslieMr. Matthew LorenceMr. William LupienMs. Susan LussosMr. Aaron MaciasDr. Allen MartinMr. John McCartyMr. Curtis McGirtMs. Christina MehrenMr. Jip MeijerMr. Peter J. MichelMr. Don MurphyMr. Matthew MurphyMr. Christopher NawrotMs. Summer NorrisMr. Charles NovyAlbrecht Fürst Oettingen-SpielbergMrs. Carrie ORourkeMs. Terri OrtegoMs. Rachel PettitMr. Eugenio PozzoMr. Philip ProdanovicAnonymousMr. Jason ReichertMr. Danny Roberson,    In memory of Voltairine de CleyreRev. Charles RobertsMr. Andrew RobertsMr. Holger RöderMr. Frank RooneyMr. Carlos RossiMr. Anthony RozmajzlMr. Glenn M. RuffusMr. Brae Sadler,    In honor of Dave SmithMr. Michael ScarbroughMr. Edward ScottMr. Vincent ScrivensMrs. Margaret ScsasznyMr. Kurt SeidlerMr. John ShemiltDr. and Mrs. Paul L. ShelterMr. Michael SimonMr. Walter E. StepkoMr. Daniel ȘterbuleacMr. John SullivanMr. Dale SummersMrs. Nancy H. SwansonMr. Daniel S. TaylorGiovanni TestaMiss Eryn ThompsonMr. Henry TilestonMr. Joshua TurnerMr. and Mrs. Chase VentersMr. Garret WallimanMr. Steven G. WaltherMr. Gavin WaxMr. Paul F. WeberMr. Ronald R. WhiteMr. Daniel M. WinterrowdMr. Roger Woodward

     

    All donors will be listed on our home page this week. Recurring donors of $5 or more, or one-time donors of $60 or more, will receive a free copy of The Dollar Dilemma by Ron Paul.

    Mises Wire
    enOctober 04, 2020

    Nationalism and Secession

    Nationalism and Secession

    [Published in Chronicles, Nov. 1993, p. 23–25]

    With the collapse of communism all across Eastern Europe, secessionist movements are mushrooming. There are now more than a dozen independent states on the territory of the former Soviet Union, and many of its more than 100 different ethnic, religious, and linguistic groups are striving to gain independence. Yugoslavia has dissolved into various national components. Slovenia, Croatia, Serbia, and Bosnia now exist as independent states. The Czechs and the Slovaks have split and formed independent countries. There are Germans in Poland, Hungarians in Slovakia, Hungarians, Macedonians, and Albanians in Serbia, Germans and Hungarians in Romania, and Turks and Macedonians in Bulgaria who all desire independence. The events of Eastern Europe have also given new strength to secessionist movements in Western Europe: to the Scots and Irish in Great Britain, the Basques and Catalonians in Spain, the Flemish in Belgium, and the South Tyrolians and the Lega Nord in Italy.

    From a global perspective, however, mankind has moved closer than ever before to the establishment of a world government. Even before the dissolution of the Soviet Union, the United States had attained hegemonical status over Western Europe (most notably over West Germany) and the Pacific rim countries (most notably over Japan)—as indicated by the presence of American troops and military bases, by the NATO and SEATO pacts, by the role of the American dollar as the ultimate international reserve currency and of the U.S. Federal Reserve System as the “lender” or “liquidity provider” of last resort for the entire Western banking system, and by institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. Moreover, under American hegemony the political integration of Western Europe has steadily advanced. With the establishment of a European Central Bank and a European Currency Unit (ECU), the European Community will be complete before the turn of the century. In the absence of the Soviet Empire and its military threat, the United States has emerged as the world’s sole and undisputed military superpower.

    A look at history reveals yet another perspective. At the beginning of this millennium, Europe consisted of thousands of independent territorial units. Now, only a few dozen such units remain. To be sure, decentralizing forces also existed. There was the progressive disintegration of the Ottoman Empire from the 16th century until after World War I and the establishment of modern Turkey. The discontiguous Habsburg Empire was gradually dismembered from the time of its greatest expansion under Charles V until it disappeared and modern Austria was founded in 1918. However, the overriding tendency was in the opposite direction. For instance, during the second half of the 17th century, Germany consisted of some 234 countries, 51 free cities, and 1,500 independent knightly manors. By the early 19th century, the total number of all three had fallen below 50, and by 1871 unification had been achieved. The scenario in Italy was similar. Even the small states have a history of expansion and centralization. Switzerland began in 1291 as a confederation of three independent cantonal states. By 1848 it was a single (federal) state with some two dozen cantonal provinces.

    How should one interpret these phenomena? According to the orthodox view, centralization is generally a “good” and progressive movement, whereas disintegration and secession, even if sometimes unavoidable, represent an anachronism. It is assumed that larger political units—and ultimately a single world government—imply wider markets and hence increased wealth. As evidence of this, it is pointed out that economic prosperity has increased dramatically with increased centralization. However, rather than reflecting any truth, this orthodox view is more illustrative of the fact that history is typically written by its victors. Correlation or temporal coincidence do not prove causation. In fact, the relationship between economic prosperity and centralization is very different from—indeed, almost the opposite of—what orthodoxy alleges.

    Political integration (centralization) and economic (market) integration are two completely different phenomena. Political integration involves the territorial expansion of a government’s power of taxation and property regulation (expropriation). Economic integration is the extension of the interpersonal and interregional division of labor and market participation.

    In principle, in taxing and regulating (expropriating) private property owners and market income earners, all governments are counterproductive. They reduce market participation and the formation of economic wealth. Once the existence of a government has been assumed, however, no direct relationship between territorial size and economic integration exists. Switzerland and Albania are both small countries, but Switzerland exhibits a high degree of economic integration, whereas Albania does not. Both the United States and the former Soviet Union are large. Yet while there is much division of labor and market participation in the United States, in the Soviet Union, where there was virtually no private capital ownership, there was hardly any economic integration. Centralization, then, can go hand in hand with either economic progress or retrogression. Progress results whenever a less taxing and regulating government expands its territory at the expense of a more expropriative one. If the reverse occurs, centralization implies economic disintegration and retrogression.

    Yet a highly important indirect relationship exists between size and economic integration. A central government ruling over large-scale territories—much less a single world government—cannot come into existence ab ovo. Instead, all institutions with the power to tax and regulate the owners of private property must start out small. Smallness contributes to moderation, however. A small government has many close competitors, and if it taxes and regulates its own subjects visibly more than these competitors do, it is bound to suffer from emigration and a corresponding loss of future revenue. Consider a single household, or a village, as an independent territory, for instance. Could a father do to his son, or a mayor to his village, what the government of the Soviet Union did to its subjects (i.e., deny them any right to private capital ownership) or what governments all across Western Europe and the United States do to their citizens (i.e., expropriate up to 50 percent of their productive output)? Obviously not. Either there would be an immediate revolt and the government would be overthrown or emigration to another nearby household or village would ensue.

    Contrary to orthodoxy, then, it is precisely because Europe possessed a highly decentralized power structure composed of countless independent political units that explains the origin of capitalism—the expansion of market participation and of economic growth—in the Western world. It is not by accident that capitalism first flourished under conditions of extreme political decentralization: in the northern Italian city states, in southern Germany, and in the secessionist Low Countries.

    The competition among small governments for taxable subjects brings them into conflict with each other. As a result of interstate conflicts, historically drawn out over the course of centuries, a few states succeed in expanding their territories, while others are eliminated or incorporated. Which states win in this process of eliminative competition and which ones lose depends on many factors, of course. But in the long run, the decisive factor is the relative amount of economic resources at a government’s disposal. In taxing and regulating, governments do not positively contribute to the creation of economic wealth. Instead, they parasitically draw on existing wealth. However, they can influence the amount of the existing wealth negatively.

    Other things being equal, the lower the tax and regulation burden imposed by a government on its domestic economy, the larger its population tends to grow (for internal reasons as well as immigration factors), and the larger the amount of domestically produced wealth on which it can draw in its conflicts with neighboring competitors. For this reason centralization is frequently progressive. States that tax and regulate their domestic economies little—liberal states—tend to defeat, and expand their territories at the expense of, nonliberal ones. This accounts for the outbreak of the “industrial revolution” in centralized England and France. It explains why in the course of the 19th century Western Europe came to dominate the rest of the world (rather than the other way around), and why this colonialism was generally progressive. Furthermore, it explains the rise of the United States to the rank of superpower in the course of the 20th century.

    However, the further the process of more liberal governments defeating less liberal ones proceeds—i.e., the larger the territories, the fewer and more distant the remaining competitors, and thus the more costly international migration—the lower a government’s incentive to continue in its domestic liberalism will be. As one approaches the limit of a One World state, all possibilities of voting with one’s feet against a government disappear. Wherever one goes, the same tax and regulation structure applies. Thus relieved of the problem of emigration, a fundamental rein on the expansion of governmental power is gone. This explains the course of the 20th century: with World War I, and even more with World War II, the United States attained hegemony over Western Europe and became heir to its vast colonial empires. A decisive step in the direction of global unification, therefore, was taken with the establishment of a pax Americana. And indeed, throughout the entire period the United States, Western Europe, and most of the rest of the world have suffered from a steady and dramatic growth of government power, taxation, and regulatory expropriation.

    What then is the role of secession? Initially, secession is nothing more than a shifting of control over the nationalized wealth from a larger, central government to a smaller, regional one. Whether this will lead to more or less economic integration and prosperity depends on the new regional government’s policies. However, the sole fact of secession has an immediate positive impact on production, for one of the most important reasons for secession is typically the belief on the part of the secessionists that they and their territory are being exploited by others. The Slovenes felt that they were being robbed systematically by the Serbs and the Serbian-dominated central Yugoslavian government, and the Baltics resented the fact that they had to pay tribute to the Russians and the Russian-dominated government of the Soviet Union. By virtue of secession, hegemonic domestic relations are replaced by contractual—mutually beneficial—foreign relations. Instead of forced integration there is voluntary separation.

    Forced integration, illustrated by such measures as busing, rent controls, antidiscrimination laws, and “free immigration,” invariably creates tension, hatred, and conflict. In contrast, voluntary separation leads to social harmony and peace. Under forced integration any mistake can be blamed on a foreign group or culture and all success claimed as one’s own, and hence there is little or no reason for any culture to learn from another. Under a regime of “separate but equal,” one must face up to the reality not only of cultural diversity but in particular of visibly distinct ranks of cultural advancement. If a secessionist people wishes to improve or maintain its position vis-á-vis a competing one, nothing but discriminative learning will help. It must imitate, assimilate, and, if possible, improve upon the skills, traits, practices, and rules characteristic of more advanced cultures, and it must avoid those characteristic of less advanced societies. Rather than promote a downward leveling of cultures as under forced integration, secession stimulates a cooperative process of cultural selection and advancement.

    Moreover, although everything else depends on the new regional government’s domestic policies and although no direct relationship between size and economic integration exists, there is an important indirect connection. Just as political centralization ultimately tends to promote economic disintegration, so secession tends to advance integration and economic development. First, secession always involves the breaking away of a smaller from a larger population and is thus a vote against the principle of democracy and majoritarian ownership in favor of private, decentralized property. More importantly, secession always involves increased opportunities for interregional migration, and a secessionist government is immediately confronted with the specter of emigration. To avoid the loss of its most productive subjects, it is under increased pressure to adopt comparatively liberal domestic policies by allowing more private property and imposing a lower tax and regulation burden than its neighbors. Ultimately, with as many territories as separate households, villages, or towns, the opportunities for economically motivated emigration would be maximized, and government power over a domestic economy minimized.

    Specifically, the smaller the country, the greater will be the pressure to opt for free trade rather than protectionism. All government interference with foreign trade forcibly limits the range of mutually beneficial interterritorial exchanges and thus leads to relative impoverishment, at home as well as abroad. But the smaller a territory and its internal markets, the more dramatic this effect will be. A country the size of Russia, for instance, might attain comparatively high standards of living even if it renounced all foreign trade, provided it possessed an unrestricted internal capital and consumer goods market. In contrast, if predominantly Serbian cities or counties seceded from surrounding Croatia, and if they pursued the same protectionism, this would likely spell disaster. Consider a single household as the conceivably smallest secessionist unit. By engaging in unrestricted free trade, even the smallest territory can be fully integrated into the world market and partake of every advantage of the division of labor, and its owners may well become the wealthiest people on earth. The existence of a single wealthy individual anywhere is living proof of this. On the other hand, if the same household owners decided to forego all interterritorial trade, abject poverty or death would result Accordingly, the smaller a territory and its internal markets, the more likely it is that it will opt for free trade.

    Secessionism, then, and the growth of separatist and regionalist movements in Eastern and Western Europe represent not an anachronism but potentially the most progressive historical forces. Secession increases ethnic, linguistic, religious, and cultural diversity, while in the course of centuries of centralization hundreds of distinct cultures were stamped out. It will end the forced integration brought about as a result of centralization, and rather than stimulating social strife and cultural leveling, it will promote the peaceful, cooperative competition of different, territorially separate cultures. In particular, it eliminates the immigration problem increasingly plaguing the countries of Western Europe as well as the United States. Now, whenever a central government permits immigration, it allows foreigners to proceed—literally on government-owned roads—to any of its residents’ doorsteps, regardless of whether these residents desire such proximity to foreigners. “Free immigration” is thus to a large extent forced integration. Secession solves this problem by letting smaller territories have their own admission standards and determine independently with whom they will associate on their own territory and with whom they prefer to cooperate from a distance.

    Lastly, secession promotes economic integration and development. The process of centralization has resulted in the formation of an international, American-dominated government cartel of managed migration, trade, and fiat money; ever more invasive and burdensome governments; globalized welfare-warfare statism; and economic stagnation or even declining standards of living. Secession, if it is extensive enough, could change all of this. A Europe consisting of hundreds of distinct countries, regions, and cantons, of thousands of independent free cities (such as the present-day “oddities” of Monaco, San Marino, and Andorra), with the greatly increased opportunities for economically motivated migration that would result, would be one of small, liberal governments economically integrated through free trade and an international commodity money such as gold. It would be a Europe of unparalleled economic growth and unprecedented prosperity.

    Mises Wire
    enAugust 21, 2020

    Government

    Government

    [Excerpt from chapter 3 of the Bastiat Collection.]

    I wish someone would offer a prize—not of a hundred francs, but of a million, with crowns, medals and ribbons—for a good, simple and intelligible definition of the word “Government.”This section was first published in 1848.

    What an immense service it would confer on society!

    The Government! What is it? Where is it? what does it do? what ought it to do? All we know is, that it is a mysterious personage; and assuredly, it is the most solicited, the most tormented, the most overwhelmed, the most admired, the most accused, the most invoked, and the most provoked, of any personage in the world. I have not the pleasure of knowing my reader, but I would stake ten to one that for six months he has been making Utopias, and if so, that he is looking to Government for the realization of them.

    And should the reader happen to be a lady, I have no doubt that she is sincerely desirous of seeing all the evils of suffering humanity remedied, and that she thinks this might easily be done, if Government would only undertake it.

    But, alas! that poor unfortunate personage, like Figaro, knows not to whom to listen, nor where to turn. The hundred thousand mouths of the press and of the speaker’s platform cry out all at once:

    “Organize labor and workmen.”“Do away with greed.”“Repress insolence and the tyranny of capital.”“Experiment with manure and eggs.”“Cover the country with railways.”“Irrigate the plains.”“Plant the hills.”“Make model farms.”“Found social laboratories.”“Colonize Algeria.”“Nourish children.”“Educate the youth.”“Assist the aged.”“Send the inhabitants of towns into the country.”“Equalize the profits of all trades.”“Lend money without interest to all who wish to borrow.”“Emancipate Italy, Poland, and Hungary.”“Rear and perfect the saddle-horse.”“Encourage the arts, and provide us with musicians and dancers.”“Restrict commerce, and at the same time create a merchant navy.”“Discover truth, and put a grain of reason into our heads. The mission of Government is to enlighten, to develop, to extend, to fortify, to spiritualize, and to sanctify the soul of the people.”“Do have a little patience, gentlemen,” says Government in a beseeching tone. “I will do what I can to satisfy you, but for this I must have resources. I have been preparing plans for five or six taxes, which are quite new, and not at all oppressive. You will see how willingly people will pay them.”

    Then comes a great exclamation: “No! indeed! Where is the merit of doing a thing with resources? Why, it does not deserve the name of a Government! So far from loading us with fresh taxes, we would have you withdraw the old ones. You ought to suppress:

    “The salt tax,“The tax on liquors,“The tax on letters,“Custom-house duties,“Patents.”

    In the midst of this tumult, and now that the country has two or three times changed its Government, for not having satisfied all its demands, I wanted to show that they were contradictory. But what could I have been thinking about? Could I not keep this unfortunate observation to myself?

    I have lost my character for I am looked upon as a man without heart and without feeling—a dry philosopher, an individualist, a plebeian—in a word, an economist of the English or American school. But, pardon me, sublime writers, who stop at nothing, not even at contradictions. I am wrong, without a doubt, and I would willingly retract. I should be glad enough, you may be sure, if you had really discovered a beneficent and inexhaustible being, calling itself the Government, which has bread for all mouths, work for all hands, capital for all enterprises, credit for all projects, salve for all wounds, balm for all sufferings, advice for all perplexities, solutions for all doubts, truths for all intellects, diversions for all who want them, milk for infancy, and wine for old age—which can provide for all our wants, satisfy all our curiosity, correct all our errors, repair all our faults, and exempt us henceforth from the necessity for foresight, prudence, judgment, sagacity, experience, order, economy, temperance and activity.

    What reason could I have for not desiring to see such a discovery made? Indeed, the more I reflect upon it, the more do I see that nothing could be more convenient than that we should all of us have within our reach an inexhaustible source of wealth an enlightenment—a universal physician, an unlimited pocketbook, and an infallible counselor, such as you describe Government to be. Therefore I want to have it pointed out and defined, and a prize should be offered to the first discoverer of the will-o-the-wisp. For no one would think of asserting that this precious discovery has yet been made, since up to this time everything presenting itself under the name of the Government is immediately overturned by the people, precisely because it does not fulfill the rather contradictory requirements of the program.

    I will venture to say that I fear we are in this respect the dupes of one of the strangest illusions that have ever taken possession of the human mind.

    Man recoils from trouble—from suffering; and yet he is condemned by nature to the suffering of privation, if he does not take the trouble to work. He has to choose then between these two evils. What means can he adopt to avoid both? There remains now, and there will remain, only one way, which is, to enjoy the labor of others. Such a course of conduct prevents the trouble and the enjoyment from assuming their natural proportion, and causes all the trouble to become the lot of one set of persons, and all the enjoyment that of another. This is the origin of slavery and of plunder, whatever its form may be—whether that of wars, taxes, violence, restrictions, frauds, etc.—monstrous abuses, but consistent with the thought that has given them birth. Oppression should be detested and resisted—it can hardly be called trivial.

    Slavery is subsiding, thank heaven! and on the other hand, our disposition to defend our property prevents direct and open plunder from being easy.

    One thing, however, remains—it is the original inclination that exists in all men to divide the lot of life into two parts, throwing the trouble upon others, and keeping the satisfaction for themselves. It remains to be shown under what new form this sad tendency is manifesting itself.

    The oppressor no longer acts directly and with his own powers upon his victim. No, our discretion has become too refined for that. The tyrant and his victim are still present, but there is an intermediate person between them, which is the Government—that is, the Law itself. What can be better calculated to silence our scruples, and, which is perhaps better appreciated, to overcome all resistance? We all, therefore, put in our claim under some pretext or other, and apply to Government. We say to it,

    I am dissatisfied at the proportion between my labor and my enjoyments. I should like, for the sake of restoring the desired equilibrium, to take a part of the possessions of others. But this would be dangerous. Could not you facilitate the thing for me? Could you not find me a good place? or check the industry of my competitors? or, perhaps, lend me gratuitously some capital, which you may take from its possessor? Could you not bring up my children at the public expense? or grant me some subsidies? or secure me a pension when I have attained my fiftieth year? By this means I shall gain my end with an easy conscience, for the law will have acted for me, and I shall have all the advantages of plunder, without its risk or its disgrace!

    As it is certain, on the one hand, that we are all making some similar request to the Government; and as, on the other, it is proved that Government cannot satisfy one party without adding to the labor of the others, until I can obtain another definition of the word Government, I feel authorized to give my own. Who knows but it may obtain the prize?

    Here it is:

    Government is that great fiction, through which everybody endeavors to live at the expense of everybody else.

    For now, as formerly, everyone is more or less for profiting by the labors of others. No one would dare to profess such a sentiment; he even hides it from himself; and then what is done? A medium is thought of; Government is applied to, and every class in its turn comes to it, and says, “You, who can take justifiably and honestly, take from the public, and we will partake.” Alas! Government is only too much disposed to follow this diabolical advice, for it is composed of ministers and officials—of men, in short, who, like all other men, desire in their hearts, and always seize every opportunity with eagerness, to increase their wealth and influence. Government is not slow to perceive the advantages it may derive from the part that is entrusted to it by the public. It is glad to be the judge and the master of the destinies of all; it will take much, for then a large share will remain for itself; it will multiply the number of its agents; it will enlarge the circle of its privileges; it will end by appropriating a ruinous proportion.

    But the most remarkable part of it is the astonishing blindness of the public through it all. When successful soldiers used to reduce the vanquished to slavery, they were barbarous, but they were not irrational. Their object, like ours, was to live at other people’s expense, and they did not fail to do so. What are we to think of a people who never seem to suspect that reciprocal plunder is no less plunder because it is reciprocal; that it is no less criminal because it is executed legally and with order; that it adds nothing to the public good; that it diminishes it, just in proportion to the cost of the expensive medium which we call the Government?

    And it is this great chimera that we have placed, for the edification of the people, as a frontispiece to the Constitution. The following is the beginning of the preamble:

    France has constituted itself a republic for the purpose of raising all the citizens to an ever-increasing degree of morality, enlightenment, and well-being.

    Thus it is France, or an abstraction, that is to raise the French, or flesh-and-blood realities, to morality, well-being, etc. Is it not by yielding to this strange delusion that we are led to expect everything from an energy not our own? Is it not announcing that there is, independently of the French, a virtuous, enlightened, and rich being, who can and will bestow upon them its benefits? Is not this supposing, and certainly very presumptuously, that there are between France and the French—between the simple, abridged, and abstract denomination of all the individualities, and these individualities themselves—relations as of father to son, tutor to his pupil, professor to his scholar? I know it is often said, metaphorically, “the country is a tender mother.” But to show the inanity of the constitutional proposition, it is only needed to show that it may be reversed, not only without inconvenience, but even with advantage. Would it be less exact to say,

    The French have constituted themselves a Republic, to raise France to an ever-increasing degree of morality, enlightenment, and well-being.

    Now, where is the value of an axiom where the subject and the attribute may change places without inconvenience? Everybody understands what is meant by this, “The mother will feed the child.” But it would be ridiculous to say, “The child will feed the mother.”

    The Americans formed a different idea of the relations of the citizens with the Government when they placed these simple words at the head of their Constitution:

    We, the people of the United States, for the purpose of forming a more perfect union, of establishing justice, of securing interior tranquility, of providing for our common defense, of increasing the general well-being, and of securing the benefits of liberty to ourselves and to our posterity, decree, etc.

    Here there is no chimerical creation, no abstraction, from which the citizens may demand everything. They expect nothing except from themselves and their own energy.

    If I may be permitted to criticize the first words of our Constitution, I would remark that what I complain of is something more than a mere metaphysical allusion, as might seem at first sight.

    I contend that this deification of Government has been in past times, and will be hereafter, a fertile source of calamities and revolutions.

    There is the public on one side, Government on the other, considered as two distinct beings; the latter bound to bestow upon the former, and the former having the right to claim from the latter, all imaginable human benefits. What will be the consequence?

    In fact, Government is not impotent, and cannot be so. It has two hands—one to receive and the other to give; in other words, it has a rough hand and a smooth one. The activity of the second is necessarily subordinate to the activity of the first. Strictly, Government may take and not restore. This is evident, and may be explained by the porous and absorbing nature of its hands, which always retain a part, and sometimes the whole, of what they touch. But the thing that never was seen, and never will be seen or conceived, is, that Government can restore more to the public than it has taken from it. It is therefore ridiculous for us to appear before it in the humble attitude of beggars. It is radically impossible for it to confer a particular benefit upon any one of the individualities which constitute the community, without inflicting a greater injury upon the community as a whole.

    Our requisitions, therefore, place it in a dilemma.

    If it refuses to grant the requests made to it, it is accused of weakness, ill-will, and incapacity. If it endeavors to grant them, it is obliged to load the people with fresh taxes—to do more harm than good, and to bring upon itself from another quarter the general displeasure.

    Thus, the public has two hopes, and Government makes two promises—many benefits and no taxes. Hopes and promises that, being contradictory, can never be realized.

    Now, is not this the cause of all our revolutions? For between the Government, which lavishes promises which it is impossible to perform, and the public, which has conceived hopes which can never be realized, two classes of men interpose—the ambitious and the Utopians. It is circumstances which give these their cue. It is enough if these vassals of popularity cry out to the people—“The authorities are deceiving you; if we were in their place, we would load you with benefits and exempt you from taxes.”

    And the people believe, and the people hope, and the people make a revolution!

    No sooner are their friends at the head of affairs, than they are called upon to redeem their pledge. “Give us work, bread, assistance, credit, education, colonies,” say the people; “and at the same time protect us, as you promised, from the taxes.”

    The new Government is no less embarrassed than the former one, for it soon finds that it is much easier to promise than to perform. It tries to gain time, for this is necessary for maturing its vast projects. At first, it makes a few timid attempts: on one hand it institutes a little elementary instruction; on the other, it makes a little reduction in the liquor tax (1850). But the contradiction is forever rearing its ugly head; if it would be philanthropic, it must raise taxes; if it neglects its taxing, it must abstain from being philanthropic.

    These two promises are forever clashing with each other; it cannot be otherwise. To live upon credit, which is the same as exhausting the future, is certainly a present means of reconciling them: an attempt is made to do a little good now, at the expense of a great deal of harm in future. But such proceedings call forth the specter of bankruptcy, which puts an end to credit. What is to be done then? Why, then, the new Government takes a bold step; it unites all its forces in order to maintain itself; it smothers opinion, has recourse to arbitrary measures, repudiates its former maxims, declares that it is impossible to conduct the administration except at the risk of being unpopular; in short, it proclaims itself governmental. And it is here that other candidates for popularity are waiting for it. They exhibit the same illusion, pass by the same way, obtain the same success, and are soon swallowed up in the same gulf.

    We had arrived at this point in February.This was written in 1849. At this time, the illusion that is the subject of this article had made more headway than at any former period in the ideas of the people, in connection with Socialist doctrines. They expected, more firmly than ever, that Government, under a republican form, would open in grand style the source of benefits and close that of taxation. “We have often been deceived,” said the people; “but we will see to it ourselves this time, and take care not to be deceived again!”

    What could the Provisional Government do? Alas! Just that which always is done in similar circumstances—make promises, and gain time. It did so, of course; and to give its promises more weight, it announced them publicly thus:

    Increase of prosperity, diminution of labor, assistance, credit, free education, agricultural colonies, cultivation of waste land, and, at the same time, reduction of the tax on salt, liquor, letters, meat; all this shall be granted when the National Assembly meets.

    The National Assembly meets, and, as it is impossible to realize two contradictory things, its task, its sad task, is to withdraw, as gently as possible, one after the other, all the decrees of the Provisional Government. However, in order somewhat to mitigate the cruelty of the deception, it is found necessary to negotiate a little. Certain engagements are fulfilled, others are, in a measure, begun, and therefore the new administration is compelled to contrive some new taxes.

    Now I transport myself in thought to a period a few months hence and ask myself with sorrowful forebodings, what will come to pass when the agents of the new Government go into the country to collect new taxes upon legacies, revenues, and the profits of agricultural traffic? It is to be hoped that my presentiments may not be verified, but I foresee a difficult part for the candidates for popularity to play.

    Read the last manifesto of the Montagnards—that which they issued on the occasion of the election of the President. It is rather long, but at length it concludes with these words: “Government ought to give a great deal to the people, and take little from them.” It is always the same tactics, or, rather, the same mistake.

    “Government is bound to give gratuitous instruction and education to all the citizens.”

    It is bound to give “A general and appropriate professional education, as much as possible adapted to the wants, the callings, and the capacities of each citizen.”

    It is bound “To teach every citizen his duty to God, to man, and to himself; to develop his sentiments, his tendencies, and his faculties; to teach him, in short, the scientific part of his labor; to make him understand his own interests, and to give him a knowledge of his rights.”

    It is bound “To place within the reach of all, literature and the arts, the patrimony of thought, the treasures of the mind, and all those intellectual enjoyments which elevate and strengthen the soul.”

    It is bound “To give compensation for every accident, from fire, inundation, etc., experienced by a citizen.” (The et cetera means more than it says.)

    It is bound “To attend to the relations of capital with labor, and to become the regulator of credit.”

    It is bound “To afford important encouragement and efficient protection to agriculture.”

    It is bound “To purchase railroads, canals, and mines; and, doubtless, to transact affairs with that industrial capacity which patronizes it.”

    It is bound “To encourage useful experiments, to promote and assist them by every means likely to make them successful. As a regulator of credit, it will exercise such extensive influence over industrial and agricultural associations as shall ensure them success.”

    Government is bound to do all this, in addition to the services to which it is already pledged; and further, it is always to maintain a menacing attitude toward foreigners; for, according to those who sign the program, “Bound together by this holy union, and by the precedents of the French Republic, we carry our wishes and hopes beyond the boundaries that despotism has placed between nations. The rights that we desire for ourselves, we desire for all those who are oppressed by the yoke of tyranny; we desire that our glorious army should still, if necessary, be the army of liberty.”

    You see that the gentle hand of Government—that good hand that gives and distributes, will be very busy under the government of the Montagnards. You think, perhaps, that it will be the same with the rough hand—that hand which dives into our pockets. Do not deceive yourselves. The aspirants after popularity would not know their trade if they had not the art, when they show the gentle hand, to conceal the rough one.

    Their reign will assuredly be the jubilee of the tax-payers.

    “It is superfluities, not necessities,” they say “that ought to be taxed.”

    Truly, it will be a happy day when the treasury, for the sake of loading us with benefits, will content itself with curtailing our superfluities!

    This is not all. The Montagnards intend that “taxation shall lose its oppressive character, and be only an act of fraternity.” Good heavens! I know it is the fashion to thrust fraternity in everywhere, but I did not imagine it would ever be put into the hands of the tax-gatherer.

    To come to the details: Those who sign the program say, “We desire the immediate abolition of those taxes that affect the absolute necessities of life, such as salt, liquors, etc., etc.

    “The reform of the tax on landed property, customs, and patents.

    “Gratuitous justice—that is, the simplification of its forms, and reduction of its expenses,” (This, no doubt, has reference to stamps.)

    Thus, the tax on landed property, customs, patents, stamps, salt, liquors, postage, all are included. These gentlemen have discovered the secret of giving an excessive activity to the gentle hand of Government, while they entirely paralyze its rough hand.

    Well, I ask the impartial reader, is it not childishness, and worse, dangerous childishness? Is it not inevitable that we shall have revolution after revolution, if there is a determination never to stop till this contradiction is realized: “To give nothing to Government and to receive much from it?”

    If the Montagnards were to come into power, would they not become the victims of the means that they employed to take possession of it?

    Citizens! In all times, two political systems have been in existence, and each may be maintained by good reasons. According to one of them, Government ought to do much, but then it ought to take much. According to the other, this twofold activity ought to be little felt. We have to choose between these two systems. But as regards the third system, which partakes of both the others, and which consists in exacting everything from Government, without giving it anything, it is chimerical, absurd, childish, contradictory, and dangerous. Those who proclaim it, for the sake of the pleasure of accusing all Governments of weakness, and thus exposing them to your attacks, are only flattering and deceiving you, while they are deceiving themselves.

    For ourselves, we consider that Government is and ought to be nothing whatever but common force organized, not to be an instrument of oppression and mutual plunder among citizens; but, on the contrary, to secure to everyone his own, and to cause justice and security to reign.

    Mises Wire
    enSeptember 21, 2019

    The History of Sin

    The History of Sin

    [Excerpt from "The Fall and Rise of Puritanical Policy in America," Journal of Libertarian Studies 12, no. 1 (1996): 143–60]

    America was colonized by Europeans seeking economic and religious liberty, with many of the colonies founded explicitly along theocratic lines. The most notorious of these groups, the Puritans, founded the Massachusetts Bay Colony. They adopted wide-ranging sumptuary legislation including restrictions on alcohol and tobacco. Despite the natural advantages of a small homogeneous group based on voluntary association, many of the measures proved to be unworkable and ineffective and had to be modified or replaced by decrees to maintain moderation.Gary North, Puritan Economic Experiments (Fort Worth, TX: Institute for Christian Economics, 1988). It is the Puritan impulse for social reform that drives the cycle of reform, prohibition, and repeal. Over time this cycle has produced Puritanical social control that has been secularized, centralized, and has achieved a kind of permanence within government bureaucracy.

    The American Revolution was an expression of political and economic independence, primarily precipitated by the British domination over trade and taxes. Americans did not want to pay British excises on the products they consumed. But equally important was the desire to eliminate British control over international trade that enriched the English at American expense. “Sinful” goods like alcohol, tea, and tobacco were targets of British colonial policy. Tobacco farmers, for example, were forced to export their tobacco to England at extremely unfavorable terms.John S. Bassett, A Short History of the United States: 1492-1929 (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1932), p. 143.

    The success of the radical American Revolution ushered in a multitude of reforms honoring individualism at the expense of traditional hegemony. Slavery was abolished in several Northern states and freedom to manumit slaves was established in several Southern states. After writing the Declaration of Independence, Thomas Jefferson set about abolishing entail, eliminating primogeniture, and establishing religious freedom in Virginia, the first time this had ever been done in so complete a form. Freedom of religion was established in several other states and many established churches lost their state monopoly.

    The late eighteenth century produced not only the American Revolution but also the Industrial Revolution. The new republic grew in size and population and prospered economically. Manufacturing, agriculture, and trade thrived in the northeast. The plantation economy of the South prospered and expanded, while the Northwest Territory was explored and settled.

    The freedom from British dominion and the economic growth that followed the war resulted in fundamental changes in the production and consumption of alcohol. New England lost its advantage in the production of rum while western grain farmers developed an advantage in the production of whiskey. With the rise of whiskey, the long term trend of lower prices for spirits continued. Lower prices combined with the new prosperity and freedom to generate increased consumption of alcohol.

    Consumption of spirits continued to increase after the Revolution, peaking during the 1820s. Despite the fact that consumption was greater than ever before or since, America was not a nation of drunkards, and public drunkenness was not common. Alcohol consumption in America was comparable to European patterns.W.J. Rorabaugh suggests that problem drinking was rare. The two types of drinking most prominent were dietary drinking, which involved numerous small servings throughout the day as a substitute for food and water, and communal binge drinking in which the entire town might get intoxicated in celebrations, such as Independence Day, harvest, weddings, and public events such as elections, generally less than once per month. See W.J. Rorabaugh, The Alcoholic Republic: An American Tradition (New York: Oxford University Press, 1979), pp. 5­21.

    Not all Americans felt the same way about the progress and freedom generated by these revolutionary spirits. Many of these grumblers had benefited from English colonial rule as administrators, tax collectors, and bureaucrats. Others benefitted from playing key roles in the system of triangular trade which saw New Englanders sell their rum and other products, while African slaves were transported on the “middle passage” to the West Indian sugar islands where the slaves were sold in order to purchase molasses, the necessary ingredient for the burgeoning New England rum industry.Many of the smaller towns of New England, especially Boston and the Rhode Island ports benefitted materially from the production of rum and the slave trade, see Bassett, A Short History, pp. 140-145.

    The Revolution thus posed a threat to some members of the ruling upper classes who controlled colonial society. A primary symbol of this threat to their hegemony was alcohol consumption. In colonial America, politicians controlled the issuance of licenses to sell spirits, the wealthy owned the taverns, and the clergy monitored consumption in the taverns. Spirits were expensive enough that only the wealthy could regularly afford these goods in large quantities. Public intoxication was viewed as a kind of status symbol.

    The elite’s first line of defense against alcohol consumption by the lower classes had been the licensing of taverns. However, this measure had already lost much of its clout by 1764 when Benjamin Franklin’s Pennsylvania Gazette labeled the tavern a “Pest to Society.” John Adams had led a crusade in 1760 to restrict or reduce the number of licenses in Massachusetts but was ridiculed by the public and defeated in his effort. As the “seedbed of the Revolution,” the tavern was greatly strengthened (by victory over England) against the elites who sought to control alcohol consumption with policies of regulation and taxation.

    The first anti-alcohol movement in the Republic turned to the British example of imposing excise taxes on spirits. After various anti-spirit measures failed at the state level, temperance advocates began calling for federal action, but no action was forthcoming until the overthrow of the Articles of Confederation. Alexander Hamilton had advocated the use of high excise taxes on spirits in the Federalist Papers and lobbied hard for such a tax as the Secretary of the Treasury.

    The excise tax was eventually passed by Congress under the pressure of a budgetary shortfall, but was angrily opposed by citizens of the west and south. By 1794 hostilities erupted into open warfare known as the Whiskey Rebellion. This widespread revolt was concentrated in western Pennsylvania, but also effected parts of Maryland, Virginia, Kentucky, South Carolina and had support in parts of New York, the Northwest Territory, and in the Southwest.See Mary K. Tachau, “The Whiskey Rebellion in Kentucky: A Forgotten Episode of Civil Disobedience,” Journal of the Early Republic, Vol. 2 (Fall 1982), pp. 239-259. The rebels called for secession, sacked the federal tax commissioners, made advances on Fort Pitt, and threatened the federal arsenals at Pittsburgh and Frederick Maryland.

    To surpress the revolt and collect the tax, George Washington and Alexander Hamilton nationalized the militia and sent a massive army into western Pennsylvania to crush the nucleus of the rebellion. Larger than most armies of the Revolutionary war, the “Watermelon Army” had more soldiers than western Pennsylvania had men of military age and was probably more than ten times the number needed to suppress the revolt. Despite this massive demonstration of federal commitment to tyranny and union, the suppression of open revolt was anything but a decisive triumph for the “friends of order” over the “friends of liberty.”

    The excise tax remained difficult to collect, as western farmers continued to oppose the excise tax resulting in the costs of collection exceeding the revenue collected in the West. The Rebellion also solidified Jeffersonian opposition to the Hamiltonian nationalists. The majority of Americans now recognized that the Hamiltonians held a Tory ideology and were using the same methods and tactics as the British had used earlier. The friends of order had more in common with the enemies of the Revolution than with most Americans. Jefferson’s Republican government abolished the whiskey excise and all other internal taxes, establishing libertarianism as the dominant ideology in national government for the period 1800–1860.On this see Thomas P. Slaughter, The Whiskey Rebellion: Frontier Epilogue to the American Revolution (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986). It has been shown that the western farmers’ economic rationale for fighting was more as consumers of whiskey than as producers. See David O. Whitten, “An Economic Inquiry into the Whiskey Rebellion of 1794,” Agricultural History 49, No. 3 (July 1975), pp. 491-504.

    The war was not, however, a total loss to George Washington and his supporters. The cost of the army was very large and much of the money was spent in the west. The visiting soldiers and newly cash-rich residents began a buying spree in western land. George Washington personally owned large holdings in the western lands, and decided to start selling his lands just prior to the Rebellion. Of course, the buying spree meant that Washington’s own holdings dramatically increased in price. As Thomas Slaughter observed, “the coincidence was certainly a propitious one for his finances.” Even Washington, who had gobbled up the largest and choicest parcels of land while in public service, noted that “this event having happened at the time it did was fortunate.”Slaughter, The Whiskey Rebellion, p. 224.

    The puritanical counterrevolution that would eventually undermine the libertarian structure of the Early Republica had its beginnings in the early temperance movement. One of the great contributors to the early temperance movement was Benjamin Rush, physician and signer of the Declaration of Independence. Rush published pamphlets that condemned the use of alcohol as both unhealthy for the individual and destructive to society. His views, while of questionable scientific validity, were used by temperance leaders to confirm their faith that both science and God were on their side. Rush’s position as doctor and patriot rendered his message highly effective among the intellectual classes, culminating in the conversion of Jeremy Belknap, a minister from Boston who later became President of Harvard College. Rush also promoted the anti-alcohol crusade by requiring his doctrines be taught at his medical school.

    Churches, however, were the principle players in the puritanical counterrevolution.This religious ideology is not necessarily inconsistent with the economic self-interest of the churches. Traditional Christian churches held that sin was a voluntary act even when temptation was involved. In early 19th century America, reformed or “heretical” Christians began a mass movement to make a preemptive strike at sin. These Christians believed that sinful objects were the source of temptation and consequently the cause of sin and thus had to be removed from society.This perspective on sin is analogous to an objective theory of value in economics. From the “objective” viewpoint, value and sin are innate aspects of the good, while from the subjectivist point of view, economic value and sin are matters of individual choice. They felt that alcohol hindered their ability to reorganize and purify society in their image. Quakers and Methodists were the first churches to declare their anti-alcohol beliefs and form the early temperance movement.

    This new religious perspective can be characterized as post-millennial evangelical pietistic protestantism. They were militantly zealous and emphasized preaching from the Bible. They were also pietistic in stressing Bible study, devotion, personal religious experience, and like the 17th century German religious movement, pietism, they opposed formalism and intellectualism. Most important to this counterrevolution was the doctrine of millennialism, a prophecy or belief in an ideal society that would be created by revolutionary action. Post-millennialists hold the “reformed” or “heretical” view that man himself must purge the world of sin and imperfection and establish the Kingdom of God on Earth as a prerequisite of Jesus’s second coming.Orthodox Christians, such as Catholics, Calvinists, Lutherans, and mainstream Protestants, are typically a-millennialist in that they do not believe in a literal 1000-year Kingdom of God on Earth. Pre-millenialists hold that Jesus will come again, defeat the forces of evil, and establish a Kingdom of God on Earth. Pre-millennialists are notorious for their incorrect predictions about the end of the world. Obviously, post-millennialist belief provides a wide latitude in terms of policy prescriptions. Rothbard considered the spread of post-millennialism to be a crucial factor in ideological change in America because it was post-millenialism ideology that would become the driving force behind the drive for prohibition and other efforts to drive out sin and imperfection using the coercive arm of the state.Rothbard writes about the earlier post-millennialist, Joachim of Fiore, a twelfth-century Calabrian monk who attempted to establish a heretical communist society and almost converted three popes to his beliefs. Post-millennialism continued to spring up in medieval Europe, especially in Germany and among the Anabaptists. This history is described in Norman R.C. Cohn, The Pursuit of Millennium: Revolutionary Messianism in Medieval and Reformation Europe and its Bearing on Modern Totalitarian Movements (London: Harper & Row, 1961). According to Rothbard post-millennialism is also an important component of secular movements such as Karl Marx’s communism. Adolph Hitler's Nazism and Third (1000 year) Reich could also be interpreted as a secular derivation of Joachim’s millennialism and original thesis that history would be divided into three, rather than the traditional two periods of christian doctrine. See Murray N. Rothabrd, “Karl Marx: Communist as Religious Eschatologist,” Review of Austrian Economics 4 (1990), pp. 123-79.

    Geographically, post-millennialist evangelical pietism emanated from New England where the Puritans first settled. The Puritans (who had already experimented with theocracy, witch hunts, and prohibitionism) and the Separatists evolved into the Congregational and Unitarian churches which were the state-established churches of New England. This Yankee influence spread into western New York, the Midwest, and Great Lakes region and eventually south and west as New Englanders, their clergy, and educators migrated with the nation’s expansion.Much of this migration was concentrated in areas claimed by Massachusetts and Connecticut in the Treaty of 1783. On the dispersion of the prohibitionists, see Whitney R. Cross, The Burned-over District: The Social and Intellectual History of Enthusiastic Religion in Western New York, 1800-1850 (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1950); Peter H. Odegard, [1928] Pressure Politics: The Story of the Anti-Saloon League (New York: Octagon Books, 1966).

    The first anti-alcohol organization was the Massachusetts Society for the Suppression of Intemperance, which was formed in response to the intemperance associated with the War of 1812. The American Temperance Society was organized in 1826. By 1833, the temperance movement had over one million members, largely comprised of New England evangelicals from the Baptist, Congregationalist, Methodist, and Presbyterian churches.Ironically, both the anti-alcohol movement and anti-slavery movement were centered in Boston which dominated the early colonial triangular trade in rum and slaves. This surge in prohibitionist sentiment is related to religious revivalism of the Second Great Awakening. Religious revivalism was very strong in the 1820s and 1830s throughout New England. Revivalism had always meant reform of the individual and society, but Americans saw themselves as a special case. Americans had defeated the savage Indian, nature, and the British. America was the proverbial city on the hill, an example to the world, and the most likely place for God to establish His Kingdom on Earth.

    Increased alcohol consumption may have also stimulated the temperance movement. Rorabaugh estimated that the consumption of alcohol increased from 3.5 pure gallons per capita in 1770 to almost 4 gallons in 1830. This increased consumption was the result of lower production costs, lower taxes, and higher incomes. Drinking was part of virtually every aspect of life for many in the early Republic and was a symbol of the American spirit.Rorabaugh, The Alcoholic Republic, p. 9. While it is dubious that alcohol causes sin, “sinful” behavior is clearly associated with alcohol use. Given their superstitions, heretical religious views, and limited knowledge, it is not surprising that reformers would base their efforts on this association. Early success with private prohibitionism, such as the signing of pledges of moderation and abstinence also provided reinforcement for this association.

    An added push for religious revivalism was provided by church privatization in New England. The Congregationalist Church was disestablished in 1818 in Connecticut and in 1824-1833 in Massachusetts. This period of church privatization and religious revivalism is described as follows:

    During the first half of the nineteenth century, religion in New England was changing in dramatic fashion. On the one hand, the number of preachers demanded in Connecticut and Massachusetts with respect to the population increased by more than half even as real preaching salaries almost tripled. The increase in total pastors reflected a fivefold increase in dissenting preachers. From 1800 to 1840, the proportion of dissenting preachers in these two states increased from under 20 percent to over 50 percent.Kelly Olds, “Privatizing the Church: Disestablishment in Connecticut and Massachusetts,” Journal of Political Economy 102, No. 2 (April 1994) p. 291.

    Despite the timing of privatization and religious revivalism, it is not possible to say definitively that privatization caused revivalism.In fact, many social and economic factors contributed to revivalism and the Second Great Awakening. For example, natural factors and natural disasters also contributed to revivalism. See Michael Barkun, Crucible of the Millennium: The Burned-Over District of New York in the 1840s (Syracuse, NY: Syracuse University Press, 1986), esp. chapters 6 and 7.

    However, this separation of church and state involved not only the disestablishment of churches but also a movement from tax-funded churches to the voluntary funding of churches. In 1800, 90 percent of churches in Massachusetts and Connecticut used taxation but only 30 percent did so by 1840 in Connecticut and by 1850 in Massachusetts.Olds, “Privatizing the Church,” p. 291. Economic theory can therefore provide some support for a causal connection between privatization and religious revivalism. A monopoly church with taxing power would be expected to reduce output below competitive levels and charge monopoly prices for its “services.” We would therefore expect an increase in output after the privatization-demonopolization. Theory also predicts that new firms would enter the industry and supply competing products.Again see Olds, “Privatizing the Church,” for his evidence that the established churches did have state authority, practice price discrimination, and increase output after disestablishment (privatization), and that alternative churches expanded faster than the established churches after privatization.

    As temperance groups formed and grew, several important changes took place. Initially temperance efforts were voluntary efforts to promote moderation in alcohol consumption. Members of the temperance groups were expected to lead by example and provide education and assistance to others. Over time, however, alternative groups were established that advocated abstinence from spirits and moderation in beer, wine, and cider. Eventually, even these groups were replaced with total abstinence societies in which members were required to sign an abstinence pledge. As the work of reform became more difficult over time, reform leaders became frustrated and dissatisfied with voluntary efforts and began to advocate the use of government to enforce temperance throughout society.Thornton, The Economics of Prohibition, pp. 43-45.

    Temperance forces began to organize coalitions to pass restrictive legislation. Their first reform measure was typically to replace the license system with the more restrictive local option laws which gave communities the right to prohibit local liquor sales. Other restrictive policies included minimum-quantity purchase laws (which require the individual to buy at least 15 or 28 gallons of spirits at a time) and local prohibitions. These policies were difficult to enforce and had few if any beneficial effects. The failure of these policies to satisfy prohibitionists ultimately led to the call for state-wide prohibition.

    State prohibitions were adopted in many northern states and territories between 1851 and 1855. These prohibitions were based on Maine’s law which was authored by the zealous prohibitionist, Neal Dow. The “Maine Laws” allowed for search and seizure, reduced the requirements for conviction, increased fines, created mandatory prison sentences, and called for the destruction of captured liquor.

    The rapid success of the Maine Laws was shortlived as the rapidly growing immigrant populations opposed such laws. The Maine Laws also suffered several important setbacks in court. Enforcement was difficult because professional police forces existed in only a few large cities where the law was least popular. In the emerging Republican party, prohibition was considered a divisive issue and was not enthusiastically embraced at the national level.Interestingly, the decrease in alcohol consumption that resulted from temperance and prohibitionist efforts created a 500+ calorie deficit in the adult diet leading to declines in demographic-health measures during a period of high economic growth. See Mark Thornton, “Alcohol Consumption and the Standard of Living in Antebellum America,” Atlantic Economic Journal 23, No. 2 (June 1995).

    One event seemed to have sealed the fate of the Maine Laws. Neal Dow, who was mayor of Portland, Maine in 1855, was accused of personally profiting from the government-controlled sale of alcohol.

    An angry mob assembled at the liquor agency on the night of June 2, 1855, after the existence of the liquor had become common knowledge. The mob demanded destruction of the liquor and threatened to break into the agency if the demands were not met and Neal Dow arrested for violation of his own law. Dow, who was always quick to look to force in defense of morality, assembled the local Rifle Guards. In the confrontation which followed with the stone-throwing mob, Dow ordered his troops to fire when several rioters broke into the liquor agency.Ian R. Tyrrell, Sobering Up: From Temperance to Prohibition in Antebellum America, 1800-1860 (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1979), pp. 295-299

    Dow was labeled a murderer and a fanatic, and the prohibition movement which he was instrumental in crafting quickly diminished in political significance.Frank L. Byrne, Prophet of Prohibition: Neal Dow and His Crusade (Gloucester, MA: Peter Smith, 1969), pp. 60-69.

    The rise of the Republican party was the result of a long series of attempts to form a coalition strong enough to challenge the dominance of the Democratic party. Forged from the Whig and No-Nothing Parties, the Republicans naturally captured the prohibitionist-abolitionist radicals and thereby dominated “Yankeedom.” This coalition of mercantilist parties did not directly satisfy the prohibitionist faction, but they were able to institute taxes on alcohol and tobacco that appeased the reformers and helped the Republican party to dominate American politics for decades. After the Civil War, prohibitionists became increasingly political and better organized at the national level. Their progress included the formation of the Prohibition Party, the Women’s Christian Temperance Union, and the Anti-Saloon League.

    During the period between the Civil War and the Progressive Era the post­-millennial crusade became increasingly secular. According to Barkun, the “slow nineteenth-century separation of a secular from a religious vision of the perfect society” accelerated after (and possibly because of) the Civil War and that by “the end of the nineteenth century, millennialism was dominated by secularizing tendencies” so that “by the very time that it succumbed in religious circles its secular version triumphed in the society at large.”Barkum, Crucible of the Millenium, pp. 2, 151, 29.

    With respect to prohibitionism, this period is best classified as one of “modified” prohibition. State prohibition waned to such an extent that by 1875 only three states remained “dry.” Although there was a brief resurgence in state prohibitions in the 1880s, only three states remained dry by 1904. Modified prohibition consisted of local option, high license fees and restrictive regulations. These coalition-building and seemingly pragmatic policies ironically helped establish the conditions under which national prohibition would be promoted and enacted.

    The scientific veneer of modified prohibition was provided, in part, by political economist Richard T. Ely.See Murray N. Rothbard, “World War I as Fulfillment: Power and the Intellectuals,” Journal of Libertarian Studies (Winter 1989), pp. 81-125, for more on Ely and other progressives academics. In a report to the Maryland legislature, Ely argued for a modified prohibition that consisted of local option and an annual auction of licenses for large exclusive territories (retail monopolies) for the sale of alcoholic beverages. He argued this would greatly reduce the number of establishments selling alcohol and maximize public revenue. He argued that such businesses would be easier to tax and regulate because of the greatly reduced number of establishments and the fear of losing expensive liquor licenses for violating regulations. He further argued that concentrating the liquor business via modified prohibition “drags it before the public where all its evils must be conspicuous.”Richard T. Ely, Taxation in American States and Cities (New York: Thomas Y. Crowell & Co., 1888),pp. 280-288.

    Modified prohibition was promoted as the pragmatic alternative to prohibition because it resulted in fewer saloons, higher government revenues, and reduced public drunkenness. According to The Nation, “the same story that has been told of every State in which high-license or tax laws have gone into effect. That is, they provide ‘corroborative evidence of the practical wisdom of this method of fighting the liquor evil.’” The Nation also opposed the policy of prohibition because it was not “a proper or practical method of liquor regulation,” and that “no amount of amendment or addition can make the Prohibitory Law a success.” They concluded that when in the majority use local option, but when in the minority use high taxation to control drinking and make drinkers pay for their sins. “The lesson which has been taught over and over again (is) that prohibition laws cannot be enforced except where public sentiment in their favor predominates.”The Nation, January 12, 1888, Vol. XLVI No. 1176, pp. 24-26; February 16, 1888, No. 1181, p.127; January 31, 1889, Vol. XLVIII, No. 1231, p. 83; March 14, 1889, No. 1237, pp. 214-5; April 25, 1889, No. 1243, p. 336; June 27, 1889, No. 1252, p. 515.

    Despite testimonials of its success, modified prohibition caused a plethora of problems such as black market production, smuggling, monopoly pricing, reduced quality, corrupt retail practices, graft, and political corruption. While not as evident as the problems caused by prohibition, modified prohibition did indeed drag the evils before the public. Indeed, the problems of modified prohibition were already obvious when Pennsylvania enacted its modified prohibition. The law attempted to limit corrupt practices stemming from modified prohibition by including a restriction on brewers that prevented them from financing the high license fees charged to saloon operators.The Nation, February 16, 1888, Vol. XLVI, No. 1181, p. 127. Also with respect to high taxes the National Municipal Review (January, 1935, p. 63) noted that “High taxation thus becomes the chief foundation of the illegitimate trade.” Tun Yuan Hu found this illegitimate trade to be “deeply disturbing” but he believed it could be “driven out” by reducing taxes. See The Liquor Tax in the United States, 1791-1947: A History of the Internal Revenue Taxes Imposed on Distilled Spirits by the Federal Government (New York: Columbia University Graduate School of Business, 1950), p. 86.

    The political success of modified prohibition would suggest that true prohibitionist sentiment had all but died out in the late nineteenth century. The federal excise tax on distilled spirits had been increased by 120 percent between 1868 and 1894, most non-prohibition states had enacted local option laws by 1900, and most states and local jurisdictions had enacted high license fees.Hu, The Liquor Tax, Appendix II, p. 3, shows that the federal excise tax on distilled spirits was fifty cents per tax gallon in 1868 and one dollar and ten cents in 1894. Elsewhere, Hu notes that 37 states had local option laws by 1900 (p. 49). The Nation (January 12, 1888, Vol. 46, No. 1176, p. 25) describes the high license fees in several states. Ely, Taxation, notes that in Savannah, Georgia a liquor dealer would pay a Federal license of $25, a State license of $50, a County license of $100 dollars, and a City license of $200. The bar-keepers license in Charlotte, North Carolina was $1000 (pp. 203-205). However, instead of dying out, the prohibition movement was preparing to achieve the ultimate goal of national prohibition by organizing against the saloon, developing institutions and coalitions, and experimenting with new political techniques.

    Women were an important source of support for prohibition. The leaders of the women’s suffrage movement were prohibitionists and encouraged their members to swell the ranks of prohibition organizations. The alliance was clear; women would support prohibition (and vote for it when and where they could) while prohibitionists would in turn support the women’s suffrage movement. Women would get the vote and sober husbands, while prohibitionists would reestablish social control and dry up society. In 1873, the Women’s Christian Temperance Union was formed to institutionalize this alliance.

    In 1869, the Prohibition Party was formed. Often characterized as ineffective, it played a key although often neglected role in the ultimate success of national prohibition. Its electorial success was indeed limited, but the Prohibition party provided a valuable training ground for prohibitionists in politics. The Party also introduced ideas, such as child-labor laws, direct election of senators, the income tax, woman suffrage, and national alcohol prohibition, that were absorbed into major party platforms and enacted into law. The Prohibition Party also was a major factor in the major party realignment that occurred during the 1890s in which the Democratic party embraced prohibition.

    The Anti-Saloon League was formed in 1895 as a political arm of the post-millennial evangelical protestant churches. By 1904, the League had organizations in forty-two states or territories. When Prohibition was enacted, the Anti-Saloon League could claim affiliation with over 30,000 churches and 60,000 agencies. It is important to note that the League, which was the prime mover toward national prohibition, explicitly emblemized the most prominent institution of “sin,” the government-licensed and heavily taxed saloon.Cf. Jack S. Blocker, Retreat from Reform: The Prohibition Movement in the United States, 1890-1913 (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1976), p. 157; Odegard, Pressure Politics, pp. 20-21. The central forces of prohibitionism were the Congregationalist, Quaker, Methodist, Baptist, and Presbyterian churches. These churches, their ministers and their flocks had radiated out from New England into western New York, the mid-west, and by the turn of the century eventually throughout most of the western and southern states. It is this geographic and demographic dissemination that enhanced the potential for national alcohol prohibition.

    The League completely split with the voluntary and educational efforts of past temperance movements. Coercion, propaganda, and intimidation of political candidates were the new tools. Professional reformers were paid to propagandize (often from the pulpit), in many instances making outrageous claims against blacks and Catholics. At its height, the League published over forty tons of propaganda literature each month. The League was able to shield its big contributors from public exposure by refusing to comply with the disclosure requirements of the Corrupt Practices Act.As a result, Warburton found little evidence for determining the extent of commercial rent­seeking against alcohol. Clark Warburton, The Economics of Prohibition (New York: Columbia University Press, 1932), p. 263. See also Odegard, Pressure Politics, pp. 74, 181, 210; This absence of data should not be taken to infer a lack of commercial interest in promoting prohibition.

    The League was able to refine, strengthen, and spread the prohibitionist ideology. The ideology that emerged during the Progressive Era was forged from the experience of “modified prohibition” and symbolized in the very name of its most powerful and effective political institution, the Anti-Saloon League. As Timberlake described, the saloon became the object of national opprobrium under modified prohibition:

    The liquor industry became thoroughly involved in political corruption through its connection with the saloon. The root of the trouble here was that the ordinary saloonkeeper, confronted by overcompetition, was practically forced to disobey the liquor laws and to ally himself with vice and crime in order to survive. Unable to make a living honestly, he did so dishonestly.James H. Timberlake, Prohibition and the Progressive Movement: 1900-1920 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1963), p. 110.

    Modified prohibition forced many saloons to offer breweries exclusive selling rights in exchange for payment of their annual license fees. Saloons would also disobey blue laws, serve poor quality and watered-down liquor, and employ prostitutes, professional gamblers, and pickpockets in order to generate sufficient revenues under modified prohibition. Of course all of these practices often necessitated the bribery of police and public officials.

    The success of Prohibition depended vitally on defining its goal as ridding America of the crime and vice-ridden saloon that was corrupting both the political leadership and the poor immigrants who relied on the saloon as a center of entertainment, politics, and much more. Indeed, destroying the saloon would achieve an underlying goal of prohibitionists — providing the old-stock protestants with a method of social control over the “drinking class” who were largely recent Catholic immigrants from countries such as Ireland, Italy, and Germany.

    The only major remaining hurdle in the establishment of national alcohol prohibition was government revenue. The tax on alcohol products was the second largest source of revenue for the federal government prior to Prohibition. However, as Boudreaux and Pritchard have demonstrated:

    The income tax proved a viable alternative to liquor taxation for raising revenue, thus making prohibition possible. To be sure, the ideology of voters and politicians mattered, but Congress could not afford the cost in foregone tax revenue (hence, foregone wealth redistribution) that an ideological vote for prohibition entailed until the income tax demonstrated its revenue-raising potential.Donald J. Boudreaux and A.C. Pritchard, “The Price of Prohibition,” Arizona Law Review 36 No. 1 (Spring 1994), p 2.

    They also argue that the shortfall of income tax revenue during the early years of the Great Depression led to the repeal of Prohibition and restoration of alcohol tax revenues.

    In support of this tax substitution thesis, it should be recalled that it was the Prohibition party that first called for an income tax and that prohibitionists widely supported the income tax. It is also noteworthy that a tax revolt was gathering momentum in the early years of the Great Depression. The revolts began as a movement against property taxes in cities such as Chicago. Prior to Prohibition, local governments raised a great deal of revenue from high license fees, revenue which was lost with Prohibition. The repeal of Prohibition would not only lower alcohol prices, but would also reestablish revenue from license fees, thus relieving cities’ overreliance on property taxes. As Beito notes, “by the end of 1933, the effectiveness of the tax-resistance movement had started to wane.”Beito provides an excellent history of tax revolts during the Great Depression. He finds that the tax revolts ultimately failed because of a failure to develop a coherent anti-tax ideology and an overreliance on a strategy that stressed “good government.” David T. Beito, Taxpayers in Revolt: Tax Resistance During the Great Depression (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1989), p. 140.

    The Progressive era also saw the prohibitionists launch their “war” against narcotics, tobacco, marijuana, gambling, prostitution and other “imperfections” in society. In each of these wars, prohibitionists and progressives sought to stamp out “vice,” establish means of social control (particularly over immigrants and inferior races), and to provide a path toward order and perfection of society.

    During the Progressive Era the prohibitionist movement had become secularized, achieved the precedent of nationalized prohibition, and expanded its scope to cover marijuana and narcotics. The elitist, twentieth century Hamiltonians had established their control over American society.

    The Lost Fifth Volume of <em>Conceived in Liberty</em>

    The Lost Fifth Volume of <em>Conceived in Liberty</em>

    Murray Rothbard was a genius. One aspect of this was his writing as an American historian. He was every bit as significant a scholar here as he was as an economist and philosopher.

    For example, there is his stunning four-volume history of early America from Jamestown to the end of the American Revolutionary War. His brilliance and originality are on display, as he deftly handles a huge amount of research including a vast array of hitherto unknown facts.

    Murray is, as always, a power-elite analyst, and looks at family and financial interests of famous men, as well as their motivations and real ideologies. Standard historians shun this as politically incorrect, but in Murray’s hands, it explains so much.

    Murray writes, of course, from a libertarian perspective, and also brings to light little-known libertarian writers and activists. History has seldom been this exciting.

    But there is one tragic note. Conceived in Liberty was supposed to be a five-volume work, ending with the adoption of the Constitution. And, indeed, Murray wrote the fifth volume, the most revisionist of all. He did it in longhand on legal yellow pads, and used a dictating machine a friend had given him. His wife Joey would use the recording to type the manuscript.

    I know that sort of machine, since my father had one. As you spoke into the microphone, it would inscribe clear plastic discs with your recorded words. Murray dictated the entire book, but when he finished it over many days, all the discs were gibberish.

    Even experts couldn’t fix the disaster, so Murray — frustrated — put his huge handwritten manuscript aside, to take up other projects. He intended to get back to the fifth volume, but died before he could do so.

    Murray left all his papers and books to the Mises Institute, honoring me as his literary executor. But I was never able to decipher his handwriting; not even Joey could do so, nor others I consulted. I hated the situation, but saw no way out of it. Then the young professor and Rothbardian Patrick Newman came upon the manuscript while he was doing other work in the Mises Institute archives, and astoundingly, he was able, with great difficulty, to read Murray’s handwriting.

    So you can imagine the celebration that ensued. We were all thrilled with the book. It is compelling, radical, original, brilliant. It revivifies the first four volumes of Conceived in Liberty, and is a delight to read, with a great introduction by Patrick, who also edited Murray’s hitherto unpublished book, The Progressive Era. As you can imagine, we’re very proud of our former student. I can almost hear Murray exclaiming, “Attaboy, Patrick!”

    The fifth volume, entitled The New Republic, 1784–1791, charts the course from the freeing of the 13 states from British mercantilism to their shackling with a new American form of it.

    For Murray sees the Constitution, not as a document enshrining liberty, but as the charter of a new, powerful, centralized government designed by Madison, Hamilton, and their cohorts in a coup at Philadelphia.

    The centralizers convinced the Continental Congress to wage a traditional, centrally planned, hugely expensive war, rather than a volunteer, libertarian guerrilla action. This ensured many evils, from paper money inflation to high taxes, from conscription to price controls and seizure of goods. Ironically, it was the guerrilla leaders who actually won the war, and not General Washington, as Murray demonstrates.

    Even the post-war Articles of Confederation mixed centralizing provisions with libertarian ones. The centralizers dishonestly dubbed themselves “Federalists,” and their libertarian opponents “Antifederalists.”

    They proved to be effective propagandists in lying to the people of the 13 states, and intimidating their leaders. Eventually the Constitution was ratified by 12 states, with only little Rhode Island refusing. So the central government threatened a trade war, and Rhode Island succumbed.

    The Antifederalists, a minority, became strict constructionists to fight for freedom under the Constitution. But virtually all their predictions about future power grabs came true.

    To get the Constitution passed, however, the opponents were able to demand a Bill of Rights. But the wily Madison made them as weak as possible, ignoring the stronger protections that the opponents wanted.

    The fight for freedom continues to this day, of course, despite our giant warfare, welfare, and police state. As the fifth volume, like the rest of Conceived in Liberty, makes clear, we have an extraordinary American heritage. Heroes, known and unknown, are our inspiration. Villains, too, we must know about.

    The fifth volume completes Murray’s great work, lost for decades, yet as relevant as the day he finished it. Regular American historians, ignorant of non-Keynesian economics and biased by statism, are a bane. Won’t you help us publish this corrective? It must be priced for students, sturdily bound, and widely distributed.

    Your tax-deductible donation of any amount to the fifth volume will help. Donors of $100 or more will receive a free copy of the book. If you can make a $500 donation, you will be listed in the front of this handsome work as a Donor; $1,000 as a Patron; $5,000 as a Benefactor.  

    You’ll love the Foreword by Judge Napolitano and Preface by Tom Woods.

    Help us with your generous donation to fill in this gap in American history. Help us honor Murray. Help us teach real history, instead of the usual pap.

    Mises Wire
    enMarch 25, 2019

    Young Murray Rothbard: An Autobiography

    Young Murray Rothbard: An Autobiography

    [Editors note: Recently the Mises Institute received a box of documents belonging to Murray Rothbard from our friend Justin Raimondo. We will make new material available online as we work through the collection. The following is an autobiographical essay written while Murray was still a high school student. Fans of Rothbard will not only appreciate some of the personal details about his parents and upbringing, but also how his formative years clearly influenced his later work, including his critiques of public education. He also offers some of his political views he held during World War II, long before he became "Mr. Libertarian."]

    My Parents and Their Influence 

    In order to understand the magnitude of the influence exerted on me by my parents, it is necessary to learn something of their character and background.

    My father has a very interesting and complex character, combined with a vivid background. Born near Warsaw, in Poland, he was brought up in an environment of orthodox and often fanatical Jews who isolated themselves from the Poles around them, and steeped themselves and their children in Hebrew lore. As is common with lower middle class families, there were some people who were eager to better their lot and acquire culture and western civilization. One example was my grandmother, whose ambition was confined primarily to her children, whom she imbued with her own unfulfilled cravings.

    When my father immigrated to the United States, at the age of seventeen, he had only this spirit to urged him forward. He had a great handicap in that he did not know any established language, since he had spoken only Jewish in Poland. The isolation of the Jews precluded any possibility of their learning the Polish tongue. In addition, my father has little talent for languages, Despite these obstacles, he broke away from old nationalistic ties, and through sheer will and force of character, he has obtained an extensive knowledge of the English language, has no trace of an accent, and displays a vocabulary that would shame many native Americans. Furthermore, he has by dint of ability and perseverance, risen from an impoverished immigrant to a citizen of merit and responsibility. From the very moment he set foot in America he has been imbued with an intense love of this country, and feels a lasting gratitude for the opportunities and privileges accorded to him. This intense reverence for America and all it stands for sometimes tends toward an extreme nationalistic spirit.

    My mother's background, though different, is just as colorful. Her family abounded in the traditions and characteristics of the old Russian aristocracy. My grandmother's family, especially, had reached the highest pinnacle that the Jews in Czarist Russia could have achieved, One ancestor founded the railroads in Russia, one was a brilliant lawyer, another was a prominent international banker; in short, my mother's family was raised in luxury and wealth, My grandfather, even though lower in the Russian social ladder, was still respected and beloved as a, member of the upper middle class. Unfortunately, the kindness of his heart was his undoing, and he lost nearly everything due to his lack of business sense, and to the fact that he persistently gave away large sums of money, sometimes neglecting his family's interest. Finally, my mother's family was forced to immigrate to America.

    For my mother it was a climactic change. She had been brought up without any necessity of facing the realities of life, and consequently she shut herself up in a dream world of books and literature, much as Keats had escaped to a dream world of beauty. Both my parents have always had a profound admiration and great powers of analysis of literature, and my intense interest in books very likely is an inherited trait; although my parents encouraged it in my childhood.

    Unfortunately, the literature which influenced my mother to the greatest extent was Russian literature. To this day she has an extensive knowledge of Russian writings. This literature is morbid and depressing, and preaches a type of negative idealism, which encouraged my mother's dream world.

    As I said, the new situation was drastic for my mother. She suddenly came face to face with reality. Here was a test for the adaptability which is very necessary for an immigrant. My mother met this test well, but she did not conquer it completely, as in my father's case. She managed to find occupation and to become accustomed to American life, but she has never fully understood or known American customs and beliefs. She is still bound to Russia and its mode of life by strong ties.

    The reason for this lack of complete adaptability was largely emotional and physical. She loved teaching and its ideals dearly.  Her great thirst for knowledge, however, over-taxed her limited stamina, and she was forced to give up her lofty aims, and even to lose literature, in a sense, since her resulting poor memory caused her to lose the enjoyment of books.

    Consequently, she came to the United States in a despairing mood, her ambition crushed, and adopted an attitude of bitter resignation. Thus, the spark of ambition which is primary for the adaptability of an immigrant was missing.

    It is truly remarkable, and immensely fortunate from my stand­point, that my parents possess intelligence and profundity of character to a great extent. One of the traits and interests which I have learned directly from my parents is an ability and intellectual pleasure in analyzing people, including myself. Very often my parents and I have long talks, where I present my analyses of different people, after which both my parents add their own comments. They have taken great care, however, although encouraging me to analyze character, not to present their opinions before mine, and so to unduly influence my judgment, Many times I frankly analyze both myself and my parents, and these efforts are always met with interest and understanding.

    The moments of my life that afford me the greatest enjoyment and instruction are the long discussions which I frequently have with my parents, The mutual understanding is so strong as to be ever silently present, a mute god seen appreciatively by us all. The relationship between my parents and myself has been a constant source of wonder and admiration for me, They are a brother and sister to whom I can always come for guidance and sympathy, which are backed by tender devotion, a keen insight, and intelligence. A statement made by a waiter in the hotel where I was staying this summer all-1ays comes forcibly back to me. "Gee!" he said. "You and your father are like brothers aren't you?" I could only nod my head in silent approval.

    The discussions include every valuable topic, philosophy, literature, politics, and character analyses and self-analysis, which are a source of inspiration to all of us. Our tastes in books vary widely, and offer interesting topics for debates. I prefer American and English writers almost exclusively, but I am resolved to concentrate more on Continental literature in order to widen my scope. My mother is mainly interested in Russian writers; whereas my father has universal taste, with stress laid on English and Continental authors. To show an example of my parents' liberalism and open­mindedness, in recent years I have influenced them more than they have influenced me, opening new vistas of modern American and English writings, Specifically, my father and I have become extremely interested in John Buchan, and we have both decided to read as many of his works as possible.

    My father's mind is precise, analytical, and scientific; though he is emotional, he shuns an excess of emotionalism, Because of this paradox, he has been unwilling to read poetry, despite my persistent efforts.

    When the family discussion turn to politics, my father and I take the lead, since my mother is not sufficiently interested in the subject to discuss it eagerly, and, I must confess, sometimes heatedly. My father went through all political stages in his life. According to Clemanceau’s definition, my father has both a head and a heart. Said the Old Tiger, “A man who is not a radical at twenty has no heart; he who is one at thirty has no head." My father was a radical at twenty, but he was quick to profit by his folly, strange as it appears, I always attempt to gauge my beliefs and actions by his experience, I think it is one of the cardinal faults of youth that it never profits by the experience of others. At any rate, my father taught me the intricacies of politics without prejudice, at least as without prejudice as politics could ever hope to be. However, when I became mature enough to form my own conclusions, I was not too much surprised to find that I agreed with my father on basic political principles.

    Sometimes, in my opinion, my father becomes a little imperialistic. However, my father would scorn that statement since he dislikes political labels. “Labels," he has often said to me, "mean nothing. They are only an inept means of classification, used by unintelligent people.” Radicals use them almost exclusively, classifying people as "liberals; conservatives, reactionaries, Communists; or Fascists." They conveniently leave no room for plain Americans, or people who believe in democracy. My father, contrary to the bigoted opinion of many unintelligent people with whom we come in contact, believes in progress and change. Change must be slow, however, or else our delicate system of free enterprise will be hurt. "There are no people who do not believe in change," said my father once," the only difference between them is the rate of change in which they believe," Given a due amount of reflection, that statement appears clearly and surprisingly true.

    Our attitude toward socialism is a common one. A belief in free enterprise is a basic one with my father, and has remained with me ever since I have formed ·a political philosophy. There can be no progress under a socialistic system. Under it, all incentive is lost, and initiative is: destroyed, as a result of the loss or competition. The "oh, I can always work for the government" theory will be all-pervading, and the United States which depends on growth will become stagnant. In addition, socialism inevitably leads to a great concentration of power in the government, which leads irretrievably to totalitarianism, Probably the man in America who has come nearest to representing my political beliefs is Wendell Willkie.

    My parents' disbelief in religious customs and traditions stems partly from reaction to the religious fanaticism of Old World Jews, and partly from an intelligent outlook, which if it does not deny the existence of a Deity, repudiates out-worn traditions. Antique customs are acceptable only to fanatics or people who never stop to think and examine their beliefs. Thus, I was brought up with only rare entrances to temples or synagogues and with no adherence to orthodox customs. My: mother's parents, who are steeped in European traditions, are orthodox, but my frequent first-hand observations of their adherence to religious traditions does not cause me to change my non-religious views. Consequently, in my religious beliefs, I am a mixture of an agnostic and a reform Jew. I do not think that the human race can determine whether or not there is a Deity; certainly, if there is one, our prayers will not be more successful if we are governed by out-moded customs.

    My father is the type of person who sets a goal for himself and never ceases until he reaches that goal. When he has reached, it he always sets his energies on another objective. Thus, he can never be emotionally satisfied or content, as long as there are more fields to traverse, or more possible goals. People such as my father make progress possible. However, my father is unhappy because he has never been able to climb to the top in his field, or to make any lasting contribution to science or scientific progress. His greatest hope, and my mother's too, is to see me reach the heights in any field which I choose. The hope that their child achieves more than themselves, is, I think, typical of parents. My parents, however, have confirmed their desires by action. They have spared no expense or sacrifice to give me all the advantages that I could require. I only hope that I will be capable of fulfilling their fondest dreams, and prove that all their sacrifices were not in vain.

    Early Childhood

    My parents are firm believers in a liberal home education, and have always encouraged my persistent search for knowledge. I was a very inquisitive and inquiring child; if I saw anything which puzzled me, I didn't rest until I had received a satisfactory answer. I pestered my parents unmercifully, but they were always on hand to answer my questions.  While still in my infancy, I made my first acquaintance with literature. Well, it could hardly be called literature, but it opened undreamed-of horizons for me. I was looking at an oatmeal box and saw the letters H-O. My parents explained to me what they meant, and at the age of seventeen months I mastered the alphabet. From then on, I amazed my parents by composing endless lists of poems. I was so filled with the splendor of words that verses flew from lips. When horizons of books were opened to me, I formed an intense love of reading. I read avidly and continually, gradually acquiring a grasp of literature which was advanced for my years. For example, when I was five years old, I was using the dictionary and Encyclopedia Britannica intelligently. My incessant reading finally resulted in impairing my eyesight.

    At the age of five, I formed my first acquaintance with the beauties of nature. My father brought home one of his business associates, Mr. Larry LeJeune. Mr. Le Jeune had a wide knowledge of nature, but he was especially versed in the characteristics of every variety of tree. We took a walk through a park, and I listened in open-eyed awe and wonder to his enchanting description of the trees around us. These commonplace objects, which had appeared to be drab and uninteresting, took on a new aspect of greatness. It is true that I never developed as great an interest in nature, as in literature, but I always think of that walk, whenever I come upon a tree.

    A series of accidents has bred in me a strong fear of high places. When yet an infant, I fell out of a second-story window, miraculously unhurt. A few years later I fell off a high chair, hitting my head against the wheel. In addition, I fell from a swing and a doctor's table. All these events has resulted in a fear of heights, which is still great today. A “keep my feet on the ground” policy is literal in my case.

    In my childhood, I was not much of a social success. I was always cowed and bullied by my playmates, until I finally took recourse in books. Each succeeding year this situation became more acute. At first it was a result of my natural shyness and timidity. At the delicate age of five, we moved to Staten Island, abounding in race prejudice, which added to my troubles. I was indifferent to kindergarten since I learned nothing new there, except the noble art of rope jumping, which seemed silly and ridiculous, although the other children took great delight in it. My social maladjustment persisted through public school.

    School

    A deep honesty and conscientiousness has always marked my school work. This trait is a manifestation of the inherent honesty of my character. My mother had a strong influence in its development. From my earliest days, my mother impressed me with the value of honesty. I remember how I was greatly shocked when I found that my mother had told a lie. Although I now realize that lies are sometimes necessary to spare someone's feelings, I still cannot reconcile myself to this fact. Honesty, in its broader sense, involves conscientiousness to a large extent, I cannot recall a time, except in the case of absence, that I have handed in an assignment late, or failed to do extra work if I thought it necessary. When I am absent, I try to make up my work as quickly as possible. My parents were like that in school, also. They always strived for accomplishment in the best way that they knew.

    The unhappiest period in my life was the time when I labored under the evils of a public school system. Since I was superior to the rest of the class, I was "skipped" with disconcerting rapidity. Skipping is basically unsound because the pupil misses the valuable intellectual and social foundations acquired in the lower grades. In addition, the result of skipping is to place the pupil in a class of children much older than himself, with the consequences that the student can never adjust himself properly with the other members of the class. In my case the result was disastrous. Instead of overcoming my pre-school shyness, I was more bullied and beaten; this time by boys much older than I was. Consequently, the unhappiness which I felt in early childhood was nothing compared with the misery which I bore in public school.

    Another great evil of the public school system is that it wreaks havoc on a child of superior ability. The entire method of teaching, the poor quality of the courses, the prevalent regimentation, and narrow-mindedness, all contrived to hamper me greatly. I felt myself imprisoned in a steel cage. My mind, which wanted to soar onwards, was chained to the earth, by an endless repetition of things that I knew, as well as by trifling but amazing public school restrictions. I have never been able to figure out why I had to sit with my hands folded, or why, if there was one malefactor in the group, the whole class was punished. The individual was completely forgotten in this system. No attention was given to individual needs and problems. He was swallowed up in a mass of fifty other souls. How well I remember how I chafed at the multiplication cards which the teacher held up before the class. Two times two equals four, three times two equals six; to me it all seemed a futile waste of time.

    I was in the fourth grade when all the aforementioned evils developed at a great speed. Then, I was striving to break my bonds; but in a few years I might resign myself to the system, and become mentally lazy, actually no better than the others around me. The need for immediate action was apparent.

    I remember with amusement my parents' first attempt to solve my social problem. They engaged a boxing instructor for me. My parents, with characteristic thoroughness, obtained the best one they could find. I believe he was a trainer of some lightweight champion. However, it was soon apparent to all concerned that my career was not along pugilistic lines. I'm afraid that my attempt to become a boxer was a dismal failure. However, my parents soon perceived that my difficulty was more emotional than physical. They made every possible attempt to adjust my problems through the help of the school authorities. By reading their replies, it is only now that can fully understand the incompetency of the Public school faculty. In their attitude concerning me they displayed a total ignorance of any fundamental psychology. The reason I was unhappy, they said, was that I persisted in thinking and playing differently from the rest of the group. If I would only conform to the rest of the class, my adjustment would naturally follow. They concluded that the fault was all mine, and that I exaggerated my troubles, anyway. The individual teachers, in addition, were highly eccentric and used their pupils as outlets for their emotions and idiosyncrasies. One teacher, who suffered from high blood pressure, delighted in pinching and cuffing the students on general principles. Another engaged in biting sarcastic ridicule of individual students before the class. In recent years, the public school authorities have endeavored to segregate the bright children from the average. However, a pre-requisite for the success of such a plan is a large amount of ability and sympathy on the part of the teachers.

    After the failure of my parents' efforts, they determined to seek outside information. Even today, I marvel at the exhaustive research conducted by my parents, in order to decide upon the best course to follow. They have kept a file of correspondence and other data relating to that period, and it is a tribute to their tireless perseverance and thoroughness. Every conceivable source was tapped. Every means of advice was used. They sought the guidance of psychologists, friends, journalists acquainted with the subject, and student and parent associations. I distinctly remember visiting the office of Dr. John Levy, eminent psychologist in the field of child guidance, I clearly recall the actual contour of the room where I sat alone, and the unintelligible murmur of adult voices emanating from the next room. The most momentous decision that has yet affected my life was being reached. Dr. Levy recommended unequivocally that I be transferred to a private school. He advised that I go to as small a school as possible in order to satisfy my pressing needs for individual attention and emotional adjustment.

    Acting on Dr. Levy's advice, my parents decided, in the second term of the fourth grade, to place me in Riverside School. My entrance into this school opened vast new horizons before my eyes. The importance of my transfer from public to private school cannot be overemphasized. My mind at last was free from all worthless intellectual and physical restrictions. I was free to think! I finally received a great amount of individual attention, since there were only seven students in the class. The teachers always endeavored to guide and advise me in any problems that I faced. I could express my ideas in class freely, without the psychological intimidation, which oppressed me in public school. The courses, moreover, were superior, and the teachers seemed omniscient before my inexperienced eyes. Above all, in the two years that I stayed in Riverside, I became completely adjusted to the group. In them I found equals in intelligence, and consequently, similar interests. Thus, it was easy for me to cooperate and become 

    an indissoluble unit of the class, without, however, losing my individual identity. I discovered, with gratified wonder, that the other children liked me. I had never before sensed a friendly feeling toward me by other children. The fact that many of them were my own age also made social adjustment easy.

    Toward the end of the sixth grade my fervent enthusiasm for Riverside began to wane. It had served well as a reaction to public school, but its scope was becoming too narrow. I saw that the courses and the teachers were not as excellent as I had first thought. Furthermore, I suffered from a lack of competition. A certain amount of competition is necessary to any progress, material or spiritual. With only six others in the class, competition, or any exchange of intelligent ideas, was limited.

    A specific reason for leaving Riverside was that the 7th and 8th grades were combined in one class. The full value of the junior high would be lost in such an unsound combination. For these reasons, my parents and I began looking for another private school, with a higher scholastic standing and a greater number of students. My parents thoroughly investigated many private schools. I remember my mother's account of her first visit to Birch-Wathen. She was deeply impressed and enchanted by the teachers and courses in that school. Her judgment is valuable because she has a teacher's ability to decide on the merits of teaching methods. The class that impressed her most was an English class conducted by a Miss Pendleton, which wrote compositions on the subject of fences. My mother greatly admired the challenge to the imagination in the problem, "what do you see in a fence?" It was a source of chagrin to my mother in the next two years that I did not have Miss Pendleton as an English teacher.

    I entered Birch-Wathen in the 7th grade. I remember my first day there vividly. At the foot of the stairs in the hall, I was introduced to Russell Bliss, also a new student. Instinctively, we clung to each, with the natural impulse of two children facing a new world. We walked up the stairs solemnly, led by a sympathizing teacher. The "ice was broken" by the friendly, cheerful greeting of the 8th grade teacher, Mr. Hubbard. From that day on, I have esteemed and appreciated Birch-Wathen highly.

    I was completely happy in this school. I made friends quickly and found myself an integral part of the class. The class was large enough to be a strong social unit, and its superior intelligence supplied friendly competition and opportunity for political and economic debates. Probably the greatest debate ever witnessed in the eighth grade was the famous argument over the undistributed profits tax. The discussion lasted two history periods with Mr. Hubbard as referee. Both sides compiled facts and figures, plus weighty arguments to support their claim. Dave Zabel, Alan Marks, and myself denounced the tax, while Jim Denzer, Jim Heilbrun, and David Cohen supported it. Our side won convincingly, and received an overwhelming majority vote of the class. Later, when the heat of battle had died away, Jim Denzer admitted that he didn't believe in the tax, anyway. However, I prefer to take that as an excuse for our victory.

    I found Birch-Wathen in the quality of its courses and teachers far superior to Riverside. I was grateful to the method which allowed me to delve into research problems, exploring many streams of thought, all blending into the sea of the actual subject. I found that many assignments covered a large period, so that the student could compile and organize his material. I especially admired Mr. Hubbard. In my opinion, Mr. Hubbard is an example of a perfect junior high teacher. Every student graduating from the eighth grade glows with inspiration and enthusiasm due to his friendly, challenging teaching method. His favorite question was" Why?" He forced students to find out knowledge for themselves. This was manna to my inquiring mind. Another endearing part of his teaching was his irrepressible humor. With a genial twinkle of his eye, he would point to one student and suddenly shout out the name of another poor soul dozing in some other part of the room. He kept us constantly in an uproar, and we all looked forward to his classes as a source of entertainment as well as instruction. He instituted the delightful and unorthodox practice of urging a chocolate bar for everyone during lunch hour. Several times, during his history periods, we brought radios into school to listen to news reports. In addition, Mr. Hubbard has a remarkable collection of humorous incidents, throughout the country’s schools, and read some selections at the end of each year.

    Suffice to say that we thought of Mr. Hubbard as the optimum in teaching. I have found that feeling true of every junior high student. However, his unique method is not as good for high school, since his failure to explain his subject is a burden to those who are not exceptional. His method, which was excellent for junior high, becomes extreme and impractical in high school.

    An advantage of Birch-Wathen is that the transition from elementary school to high school is small. Naturally, more work is required in high school, and the courses are entirely changed. However, the basic system of teaching, namely, the encouragement of research and intellectual freedom and development, is still there. In addition, my graduation did not cause a departure from my happy social adjustment, but an increase in scope and interests with the same friends. I believe that the character of this class, with which I have worked for the past six years, is worthy of a brief analysis:

    Our class has always been the victim of self-scorn. The tragedy of the situation is that we fail to realize our own potential value. It cannot be denied that the class, as a whole, is brilliant. The fact that we have not always shouldered enough responsibility is due in part to our innate sense of humor, which makes us laugh at everything, including ourselves. We scoff at ourselves, call ourselves stupid, and let it go at that. We close our eyes to our own value, because it is easy to do so. But the “stuff from which kings are made" is undoubtedly there. I have every reason to hope that our latent gifts will soon blossom, and become acknowledged by all.

    I have not developed an outstanding preference for one subject in high school. In general, however, history and English have given me the greatest enjoyment. I remember the amazement and consternation which I caused the class when I stated my confirmed beliefs in the type of world that should emerge after the war. I was the only one in the class who believed that Germany should be kept in a perpetual state of subjection, and I was alone in my pronouncement that the Versailles treaty failed because it was too weak. I delighted in the ensuing debate with the other members of the class. I also liked to place myself in difficult historical situations, and see how I would have met those problems. In American history, for example, I decided I would have tried to settle slavery by popular sovereignty.

    My interest in English is explained by my interest in literature and its analysis. In addition, I enjoy creative writing, and I believe I have improved, in recent years, in the ability to express my ideas.

    Although I have been bred in a scientific tradition, and I am favorable to theoretical science, I have a dislike for laboratory work, which excludes me from that line of endeavor.

    I am grateful to Birch-Wathen for the knowledge it has given me, and for the complete social adjustment which it has made possible. I didn't know true emotional or intellectual happiness before I came to Birch-Wathen. I echo the stirring words of its Alma Mater “You have shown us the portals to rich knowledge and truth. And have given us mortals, friendships so dear to youth!”

    Summers

    Until the age of eleven, I spent my summers with my parents in mountain or seashore hotels, My recollection of these early summers is hazy, since we usually spent three weeks at best away from the city. In general, however, my social activities were broader and happier than they were in school. The reason probably was that any difference in intelligence was not conspicuous in summer recreation. Thus, the attitude between other children and myself was usually good. When I reached the age of eleven, my parents and I decided that, I should go to camp. My enthusiasm for this project was great, and my parents felt that I would learn to live and get along with, other people. My father, however, was rather skeptical, "I'll try anything once," he remarked drily.

    The director of the camp asserted that he was an idealist, motivated solely by a humanitarian interest in children. He was a forceful-looking man, with a shining goatee and an imposing stature, and he managed to convince us of the, superior qualities of his camp. To be sure, this camp was not an ordinary one. It was one of the best in New York, and was recommended highly by Parents' Magazine. My parents, who made sure of its high rating, never rush blindly into any venture. Indeed, the food was excellent, and could not be excelled anywhere. However, after the first novelty wore off, I saw that the camp's qualities ended there. The heralded activities were almost, nil; the campers could only sit and mope all day. Mr. Robbins, the idealistic director, turned out to be an ineffectual materialist, with a blustering temper. I found that most campers lost weight solely because the bunks had the effect of a Turkish bath. However, I do owe my passion for chess to the camp. It was the only possible activity during many long hours of stagnation. The fact that no camper was sunburned offered conclusive proof that he hardly ever saw the light of day.

    My father, in addition to his other qualities, is a brilliant wit. The main centers of camp life were the rec (recreation hall), the mess (dining room), and the bunks (sleeping quarters). Commenting on the camp as a whole, he said “It's a wreck, it’s a mess, it’s the bunk!" I am convinced that camps are mainly excuses for parents who wish to rid themselves of their children during the summer. If they had their children's interests at heart, they would not blind themselves to the glaring disadvantages of camp. “A racket,” my father termed it, and I heartily agree with him. If the best camp in New York was in such a deplorable condition, what are the conditions in camps of lower quality? I shudder to think of them. I believe that camps are only excusable when they assist poor families. In all other cases I condemn them whole-heartedly.

    This disappointing summer in camp was my last, and ever since, I have had an uninterrupted succession of immensely happy summers. I gained invaluable friends during the summer, just as I developed what I hope to be lasting friendships in Birch-Wathen. My transformation from a lonely, maladjusted child to a happy, sociable one was complete. Some of my school friends decry my summer activities, which consist of an enjoyable vacation at a seaside hotel. They claim that I do nothing useful there. However, I consider it useful when I can further my own happiness, and at the same time increase the pleasure of others by social companionship. It is always useful to establish a firm relationship with society.

    Relatives

    I have already dealt with my home, school, and summer environment. My relatives come under a special category. Many of them are definitely Communist sympathizers, or pinkish radicals. Consequently, my father frequently becomes involved in heated political debates. When they cannot help but see the logic of his arguments, they just call him a reactionary, a Republican (an abhorred word, for some reason) and hide behind the shield of those generously distribute labels. I usually take part in these discussions with vehemence and a certain amount of relish. Once, in the days of the Spanish Civil War, my parents and I visited the house of an uncle, a Communist party member. Naturally, his guests were all Communists, and were vigorous in their denunciation of Franco. I startled the assembly by asserting that the republican government of Spain was elected by a minority of the people, and quoted a letter in the Times to that effect. I was immediately bombarded on all sides, but I managed to hold my own against overwhelming odds. A favorite trick of the people, when someone quotes a respectable and reliable paper such as the Times, is to cry vehemently "Do you believe everything you read in the papers?" Then they proceed to counter with grandiose statements from tabloids such as In Fact, whose editor has been listed by Max Eastman as a front for Communist organizations.

    My father's family in general are shrewd individualists, and as such, have little thought of family loyalty. They are endowed with common sense but are unintelligent. My mother's family, in contrast, has a strong sense of family devotion and loyalty. However, they do not have the common sense of my father's relations, with a few exceptions, there is little intelligence among them.  Indeed my mother and father represent the pinnacle of intelligence in their respective families. I know my mother's family very well, and I usually look on with quiet amusement at their futile worries and panics. However, this feeling is mingled with a reverent admiration for their gentle nobility of character, which reminds me strongly of the weakness and courage of Louis XVI.

    In my dealings with my relatives, I have learned not to get angry or indulge in heated personal arguments. From them I have learned the important value of tolerance. Tolerance also involves open-mindedness and a willingness to listen to other people's ideas whatever they may be.

    Interests

    I have many varied interests and hobbies. Although I can trace the development of most of them, others evolved without my conscious knowledge, and with no definite or marked beginning. My interest in music has passed through several definite stages. At: first, at the age of ten, I enthusiastically adopted piano lessons. My reason was not any great love for music, since I was barely interested in it. I started piano lessons merely because of my intense curiosity and my desire to enter new fields of endeavor. Once I had learned the rudiments of music, and some of its characteristics, I lost interest in my musical career. My finger manipulation was poor, and I saw a new horizon of music listening open before me. Whatever I had learned in piano practice helped me to understand and evaluate music. I have been a fair judge of rhythm ever since it was drilled into me by my piano teacher. Therefore, since it was clear that I was not cut out to be a musician, I gave up piano lessons after two years, and devoted my musical activities to becoming an enthusiastic spectator.

    At first I did not have much discrimination, and I accepted all types of music without attempting to formulate any special favorites. However, I was soon able to judge works of music and listen with a more critical outlook. I soon came to the conclusion that I liked swing music as well as, if not better than, classical music. The reason for my extensive interest in swing music is purely that. I obtain pleasure from hearing it. If I were able to derive inspiration from any form of music, I would be interested primarily in classical music. However, it is impossible for music to hold any inspiration for me. As a source of enjoyment, therefore, I think that swing is at least equal to classical music.

    Likewise, painting has never interested me to any great extent because I can receive no inspiration from looking at a great work of art. If I tried, I could probably become expert in criticizing the technical qualities of a painting, but I could never become uplifted by it. In fact, of all the creative arts, literature is the only one that can inspire or elevate me forcibly.

    In contrast to the development of my interest in music, I cannot account definitely for my devotion to sports. It did not result from any single event or start in any given period. I only know that I have become a voracious follower of sports, in all its phases and forms. Consequently, my knowledge of both major and minor sports is widespread. The public should realize the full importance of athletics in American life. Not only does it provide an interesting diversion for care-worn people, but it also serves to build up a nation's stamina.

    However, my interest for violent athletics stops with the newspaper and the sidelines; when I seek personal athletic recreation, I prefer quieter games such as table tennis and chess. I have a definite reason for my attraction to chess. Chess, aside from its entertaining features, teaches farsightedness, circumspection, ability to think and act fast, and analysis of problems. I think that the main fascination that chess holds is that the player is a general directing his forces. There are all the difficulties, strategies, and tactics of modern warfare. Chess embodies all the challenging intellectual problems of war, without its horrible bloodshed and slaughter.

    My character consists of many, strange, contrasts. Although, I am devoted to reading and quiet pursuits, I have a keen enjoyment of dramatics. I have always excelled in acting, and I revel in a dramatic portrayal of moods and, ideas. In addition, when I find, any article which I particularly like, I enjoy reading it for my parents, with all the drama that I can put into my voice, although I realize that my parents probably would much prefer to read it themselves. If I were in their position, I certainly could concentrate better by reading the article myself. However, my relish is so great that I continue in my unwelcome course. I also like to sing for my parents, who bear this great torture with good grace.

    I have always had a keen interest in political and economic problems, and in current events, as a source of knowledge and of discussion. I think that it is the duty of every American citizen to acquaint himself with these problems, in order to contribute intelligently to any national effort, in time of war or peace.

    A Look Into the Future

    As I turn my eyes from the past and present to the future, I am unappalled by the fact that my course is undecided at present. I have many fields of interest, and it is difficult to choose one for specialization. However, I know that I will do my best in any field I choose. Society can only benefit if each individual makes his greatest effort. This fact is apparent in wartime, but it applies also to peace conditions.

    I do not believe that the advent of war has changed my outlook. War has only brought it into sharper focus and crystallization. I am even more determined mow to do my utmost to serve this nation.

    I face college with keen interest and anticipation. I welcome the greater freedom and the necessity for self-discipline which are the characteristics of college. Some people believe that the only way to be free of parental restriction is to go to an out-of-town school. In my case, however, any misunderstandings can always be solved by, intelligent and reasonable discussion. Therefore, I am not hampered by unnecessary parental restriction, and I feel free to choose a college solely on its own merits. College becomes increasingly important in wartime, for the need for a comprehensive education of youth becomes greater.  A college training enables anyone to cope, to a greater degree, with any national problems he or she is called on to face.

    With all men and women striving for the common welfare, I see, in the future an America, perhaps a world, in war or in peace, sounding the call of progress, of civilization, of humanity, and taking care that "government of the people, by the people, and for the people, shall not perish from the earth!"

    Liberty Defined

    Liberty Defined

    Liberty means to exercise human rights in any manner a person chooses so long as it does not interfere with the exercise of the rights of others. This means, above all else, keeping government out of our lives. Only this path leads to the unleashing of human energies that build civilization, provide security, generate wealth, and protect the people from systematic rights violations. In this sense, only liberty can truly ward off tyranny, the great and eternal foe of mankind.

    The definition of liberty I use is the same one that was accepted by Thomas Jefferson and his generation. It is the understanding derived from the great freedom tradition, for Jefferson himself took his understanding from John Locke (1632–1704). I use the term “liberal” without irony or contempt, for the liberal tradition in the true sense, dating from the late Middle Ages until the early part of the twentieth century, was devoted to freeing society from the shackles of the state. This is an agenda I embrace, and one that I believe all should embrace.

    To believe in liberty is not to believe in any particular social and economic outcome. It is to trust in the spontaneous order that emerges when the state does not intervene in human volition and human cooperation. It permits people to work out their problems for themselves, build lives for themselves, take risks and accept responsibility for the results, and make their own decisions.

    Our standards of living are made possible by the blessed institution of liberty. When liberty is under attack, everything we hold dear is under attack. Governments, by their very nature, notoriously compete with liberty, even when the stated purpose for establishing a particular government is to protect liberty.

    Take the United States, for example. Our country was established with the greatest ideals and respect for individual freedom ever known. Yet look at where we are today: runaway spending and uncontrollable debt; a monstrous bureaucracy regulating our every move; total disregard for private property, free markets, sound money, and personal privacy; and a foreign policy of military expansionism. The restraints placed on our government in the Constitution by the Founders did not work. Powerful special interests rule, and there seems to be no way to fight against them. While the middle class is being destroyed, the poor suffer, the justly rich are being looted, and the unjustly rich are getting richer. The wealth of the country has fallen into the hands of a few at the expense of the many. Some say this is because of a lack of regulations on Wall Street, but that is not right. The root of this issue reaches far deeper than that.

    The threat to liberty is not limited to the United States. Dollar hegemony has globalized the crisis. Nothing like this has ever happened before. All economies are interrelated and dependent on the dollar’s maintaining its value, while at the same time the endless expansion of the dollar money supply is expected to bail out everyone.

    This dollar globalization is made more dangerous by nearly all governments acting irresponsibly by expanding their powers and living beyond their means. Worldwide debt is a problem that will continue to grow if we continue on this path. Yet all governments, and especially ours, do not hesitate to further expand their powers at the expense of liberty in a futile effort to force an outcome of their design on us. They simply expand and plummet further into debt.

    Understanding how governments always compete with liberty and destroy progress, creativity, and prosperity is crucial to our effort to reverse the course on which we find ourselves. The contest between abusive government power and individual freedom is an age-old problem. The concept of liberty, recognized as a natural right, has required thousands of years to be understood by the masses in reaction to the tyranny imposed by those whose only desire is to rule over others and live off their enslavement.

    This conflict was understood by the defenders of the Roman Republic, the Israelites of the Old Testament, the rebellious barons of 1215 who demanded the right of habeas corpus, and certainly by the Founders of America, who imagined the possibility of a society without kings and despots and thereby established a framework that has inspired liberation movements ever since. It is understood by growing numbers of people who are crying out for answers and demanding an end to Washington’s hegemony over the world.

    And yet even among the friends of liberty, many people are deceived into believing that government can make them safe from all harm, provide fairly distributed economic security, and improve individual moral behavior. If the government is granted a monopoly on the use of force to achieve these goals, history shows that that power is always abused. Every single time.

    Over the centuries, progress has been made in understanding the concept of individual liberty and the need to constantly remain vigilant in order to limit government’s abuse of its powers. Though steady progress has been made, periodic setbacks and stagnations have occurred. For the past one hundred years, the United States and most of the world have witnessed a setback for the cause of liberty. Despite all the advances in technology, despite a more refined understanding of the rights of minorities, despite all the economic advances, the individual has far less protection against the state than a century ago.

    Since the beginning of the last century, many seeds of destruction have been planted that are now maturing into a systematic assault on our freedoms. With a horrendous financial and currency crisis both upon us and looming into the future as far as the eye can see, it has become quite apparent that national debt is unsustainable, liberty is threatened, and the people’s anger and fears are growing. Most importantly, it is now clear that government promises and panaceas are worthless. Government has once again failed and the demand for change is growing louder by the day. Just witness the dramatic back-and-forth swings of the parties in power.

    The only thing that the promises of government did was to delude the people into a false sense of security. Complacency and mistrust generated a tremendous moral hazard, causing dangerous behavior by a large number of people. Self-reliance and individual responsibility were replaced by organized thugs who weaseled their way into achieving control over the process whereby the looted wealth of the country was distributed.

    The choice we now face: further steps toward authoritarianism or a renewed effort in promoting the cause of liberty. There is no third option. This course must incorporate a modern and more sophisticated understanding of the magnificence of the market economy, especially the moral and practical urgency of monetary reform. The abysmal shortcomings of a government power that undermines the creative genius of free minds and private property must be fully understood.

    This conflict between government and liberty, brought to a boiling point by the world’s biggest bankruptcy in history, has generated the angry protests that have spontaneously broken out around the country—and the world. The producers are rebelling and the recipients of largess are angry and restless.

    The crisis demands an intellectual revolution. Fortunately, this revolution is under way, and if one earnestly looks for it, it can be found. Participation in it is open to everyone. Not only have our ideas of liberty developed over centuries, they are currently being eagerly debated, and a modern, advanced understanding of the concept is on the horizon. The Revolution is alive and well.

    The goal is liberty. The results of liberty are all the things we love, none of which can be finally provided by government. We must have the opportunity to provide them for ourselves, as individuals, as families, as a society, and as a country.

    [This is excerpted from the introduction of Ron Paul's Liberty Defined: 50 Essential Issues that Affect Our Freedom.]

    An Eastern Democratic Union: A Proposal for the Establishment of a Durable Peace in Eastern Europe

    An Eastern Democratic Union: A Proposal for the Establishment of a Durable Peace in Eastern Europe

    [This essay, written in October 1941, in one of Mises's lesser-known works and explores the use of a union of Eastern European states in addressing geopolitical threats in the region. Readers may be struck by how far Mises goes in supporting a strong central government in this case. We post it here for purposes of prompting discussion.]In his biography of Mises, Last Knight of Liberalism,  Guido Hulsmann describes the essay:"Planning for after the war still occupied a prominent place in Mises’s work. On May 20, 1941, he reported ... that he had made good progress on his research project: a study of the social and economic problems of Central and Eastern Europe, which Mises hoped could serve as a basis for postwar reconstruction in this region. He said he would start writing it soon, and he must have finished it by mid-July, when he sent out copies to friends and colleagues. In this 43-page memorandum, Mises restated the political and economic case for the establishment of an East-European Union with a strong central government: growth through free trade and laissez-faire, response to the problems of linguistic minorities, and protection against the three mighty neighbors." -Ed.

    I. Peace Within a World of Nationalism

    In a world of free trade and democracy no special institutions and provisions are needed in order to ensure undisturbed peaceful cooperation among all nations. In such a world, where there are neither trade barriers nor migration barriers; where the activities of governments are limited to the protection of the lives, the health and the property of individuals against violent or fraudulent aggression; and where neither the laws nor the administration nor the tri­bunals discriminate between different groups of citizens or between citizens and foreigners; it is without any importance for the indi­vidual, where the frontiers of his country are drawn. Every indi­vidual has the opportunity to live and to work where it suits him best. Nobody can derive any advantage from a change in the political distribution of the earth's surface. No citizen can be enriched by a victorious war, which makes his country larger at the expense of other countries. War does not pay. The nations become peaceful because they consider warfare as a useless waste both of blood and of wealth.

    Our world is very different from this liberal free-trade utopia. We are living in an age when the governments are eager to further the short-run interests of some groups of their citizens at the expense of other groups of citizens and of foreigners. Ours is an age of economic nationalism. Economic nationalism is a policy which intends to improve the lot of greater or smaller groups of citizens by putting impediments in the way of foreigners. Foreign products are with­held from the domestic markets; foreign labor is banned from the com­petition on the domestic labor market. Whether these measures can really attain the ends which the governments want to attain or whether they do not in the long run hurt, in some way or other, the citizens whom they want to benefit is immaterial. The decisive point is that the great majority of our contemporaries firmly believe in the efficacy of these measures of economic nationalism. There is therefore no hope that the world will in the near future try to embark upon a policy of free trade.

    Such is the stark reality we have to face. We should not deceive ourselves by false illusions. All the arguments brought forward in order to demonstrate the disadvantages of warfare and the benefits of undisturbed peace are vain in an age of economic nationalism. Under present conditions the pacifists are mistaken when they declare that a victorious war does not pay. It is true that the individual citi­zens of Germany did not gain anything in 1871 by the conquest of Alsace-Lorraine. This was in the days of a more or less free-trade Europe. But today it is different. For instance, a conquest of Australia by the Japanese would, under present circumstances, improve the lot of every individual Japanese wage earner. It would give a great number of Japanese the opportunity to work in Australia where the natural opportunities for production are much more favorable than in the overpopulated Japanese isles. It would therefore raise the level of wages and the standard of living for all Japanese wage earners, both for those who could emigrate to Australia and for those who remain in their old country.

    Whereas in a world of universal absolute free trade every nation is eager to maintain peace, in a world of economic nationalism those nations which believe themselves strong enough are ready to profit from every opportunity to attack weaker nations. In such a world there is no solidarity of interests but a permanent latent conflict of interests which becomes manifest as soon as a good chance for prey appears. It is useless to fight this militarist bellicosity by mere moral condemna­tion. Both the Covenant of the League of Nations and the Briand-­Kellog Pact failed, because the warlike nations considered them as nothing else than, an insincere protection of the unfair privileges of the weak. The principle of collective security could not work in a milieu where every nation waged a permanent economic war against all other nations.

    We may hope that this unsatisfactory state of things will one day be replaced by a mentality of free-trade and good-will. But we have to realize that it would be foolish to believe that trade-barriers and migration-barriers will be abolished directly after this war. We therefore have to try to discover means which could make peace durable even in this age of radical nationalism.

    Nations inspired by the spirit of nationalism recognize only one argument in favor of peace, namely, that there is but little hope of success for their armed forces in waging war. What is wanted, there­fore, is some way to build up a political structure which would pre­vent the nations calling themselves "dynamic" from use of their powers for aggression.

    It is very probable that the British Empire, the American Republics and some of the democracies of Western Europe will after the war arrange for permanent political and military cooperation in order to assure themselves security against German and Japanese aggressions. Whether constructed according to the pattern laid out by Mr. Clarence Streit or in another way, such a union could peacefully settle conflicts in all countries from the left bank of the Rhine westward to the western boundaries of the British sphere of influence in Asia. But just that part of the earth whence both world wars originated would remain outside. A special scheme for a durable peace in Eastern Europe is a necessary condition for the satisfactory working of all plans to make the world safe for peace.

    II. The German Problem

    The following proposals for a new political constitution of Eastern Europe are based on two assumptions.

    The first assumption is a total defeat of Nazism. We do not have to worry about what will happen if the Nazis could end their total war by a total victory. They will exterminate some of the vanquished nations, ex­pel others from Europe and enslave the remaining ones. In the "New Order" the members of the Nazi party will rule over slaves.

    The second assumption is that the victorious British Empire and its allies will not use their total success to exterminate the German nation. We assume that the victors will neither kill all Germans nor expel them to the Arctic Circle; of course, they do not even consider such a barbaric plan. But then the German problem remains unsolved.

    This German problem consists in the firm conviction of the German nationalists that the German nation is the strongest military power on earth. The German philosophers, historians and would-be economists who have ex­pounded these doctrines for more than eighty years base their statements on the following arguments:

    1. The Germans are the most numerous among the white nations. It is a mistake to believe that the Russians or the Americans are more numerous than the Germans are. From the total figures of the inhabitants of European Russia the non-Russians (Ukrainians, White Russians, Mongolians and others) have to be deducted; the remaining numbers of the Great-Russians are in­ferior to those of the Germans. The Americans are not a homogeneous nation, but a minority of Nordics amidst Negroes, Jews, Slavs, Italians and other "inferior" races.A 1941 typed and scanned version of the essay omits the quotation marks around "inferior." The version appearing in Richard Ebeling's collection of essays Selected Writings of Ludwig von Mises Vol. 3, includes the quotation marks. See Matthew McCaffrey on Mises's views on race: "Mises on the Battle between Liberalism and Racism" -Ed.

    2. The Germans own that country which dominates strategically the whole of Europe and some parts of the two adjacent continents. They enjoy in warring the advantages of standing on interior lines.

    3. The Germans are a warlike nation; they are heroes, whereas the other white nations are peddlars (Händler), who stick to pacifism and cowardice.

    4. The genuine Germans have always been socialists in their soul and have, under the guidance first of the Hohenzollerns, later of Adolf Hitler freed themselves from the domination of Western and Jewish ideas; their mind has only superficially or temporarily been infected by Christianism, Humanitarianism, Capitalism, Utilitarianism, Liberalism, Democracy and Bolshevism.

    5. Strong, as they are, the Germans have therefore the sacred duty to conquer and to rule the world. As supermen they will tame the underdogs, to whom the appellation "human" should be denied. Such is the will of the German God, who gave power to his chosen people, the Germans.

    The main accent lies on the first of these five points. "We are a nation of 100 millions; therefore we are chosen to own the earth." It is necessary to realize that German nationalism differs from the nationalism of other nations only in the fact that the Germans believe themselves to be the strongest of all nations. They are not prepared to endure the disad­vantages which the economic nationalism of other nations imposes on them, because they feel themselves strong enough to do away with these discriminatory measures. They say: "Smaller nations may acquiesce in the actual distribution of the resources of the earth; we, the big German nation, cannot tolerate this state of things." The Nazis are full of contempt for the Norwegians and the Danes, because they themselves are many and these "Nordic" nations are small.

    As long as the world is on the line of economic nationalism and as long as there are 80 million Germans living in Europe and 20 million in non-­European countries the spirit of aggression will dominate the political thought of Germany. Nazism is not a new doctrine. It has a long history. Fichte, List, Lassalle, Lasson, Lagarde, Langbehn, Richard Wagner, Treitschke, Schmoller and Houston Stuart Chamberlain, were its sponsors. The doctrine was completely laid out in the course of the 19th century. Spengler, Spann, Sombart, Hitler and Rosenberg did not add any new ideas; they only repeated and emphasized the old slogans.

    Nothing can prevent a new German aggression but an organization of Europe which makes it hopeless for Germany to embark on a new war of con­quest. The political and military union of the Western democracies will stop Germany at its western and northern frontiers. Special provisions are needed to stop it at its eastern and southern frontiers.

    The German danger has to be seen not in the spirit of aggression which inspires most of the Germans of our time, but in the military strength of Germany, which makes such an aggression a dreadful menace. The other nations which share today a similar mentality of aggression are less danger­ous. They all would be innocuous but for the constellation created by nazified Germany's "dynamism."

    To carry out a scheme for a durable peace is not the outcome of hos­tility or hatred against Germany, Italy or Japan, the three aggressor nations of our times. The blessings of peace will benefit these nations in the same way they will favor the rest of mankind. The purpose of all plans for a lasting peace which involve the existence of these three nations is exactly this: to give to the vanquished nations after the war the op­portunity to become again incorporated into the great human society of free nations. Germans and Italians were from time immemorial foremost among the shapers of our civilization. We may hope that they will one day remember that this civilization, which they despise today, was to a great extent an achievement of sons of their own peoples.

    It is the aim of the following plan to make it unnecessary for the victorious Allies to consider any proposal which intends to treat the van­quished peoples in the same way in which the Nazis wish to treat the con­quered in case of their total victory.

    III. The Clash of Linguistic Groups

    The term "Eastern Europe" as used in this paper includes the whole territory between the eastern boundaries of Germany, Switzerland and Italy and the western borders of Russia. It reaches from the shores of the Baltic to those of the Black, of the Adriatic and of the Aegean Sea. We shall revert later to the problem of the precise de­limitation of this territory.

    This vast territory was in the Europe of the Congress of Vienna divided among Russia, the Hapsburg Empire, Prussia and Turkey. With the dissolution of the Ottoman power in Europe, with the disintegra­tion of the Austro-Hungarian Empire and with the curtailment of the Russian power the peoples of this part of the world obtained autonomy and self-government. But this independence resulted in anarchy and finally in a new partition of the territory involved among the three mighty neighbors, Germany, Russia and Italy. The order established by the treaties of 1856, 1878 and 1919 collapsed catastrophically.

    Eastern Europe is the central-seat of trouble and unrest. Both world wars arose in this territory. The units or groups which are bitterly fighting one another in Eastern Europe apply to themselves in their own languages terms which correspond to the English words nation, nationality or people. They consider a community of language as the characteristic feature of a nation. The issue in these fights is always the right to use the national idiom. The terms Germanization, Polanization, Magyarization, etc. always mean: to induce people, by violence or other methods of pressure, to replace their mother tongue by German, Polish, Hungarian, etc.

    These are not struggles among races. No distinct bodily features which the anthropologist could establish with the aid of the scientific methods of his branch of knowledge separate the men belonging to differ­ent groups. If you present one of these men to an anthropologist he will not be able to decide whether the man is a German, a Czech, a Pole or a Hungarian.

    Neither have the men belonging to one of these groups a common descent. The right banks of the Elbe river were 800 years ago inhabited by Slavs and Baltic tribes only. They became German in the course of the processes which the German historians call the colonization of the East. There was an immigration of Germans from the West and from the Southwest into this area; but the main stock of its present population are the descendants of the indigenous Slavs and Baltic peoples who under the influence of the church and the school turned to the use of the German language. Prussian chauvinists, of course, assert that the native Slavs were radically ex­terminated and that the whole present population are the descendants of German settlers. There is not the slightest proof for this doctrine, which some Prussian historians developed in order to justify the Prussian claim for hegemony in Germany. But even they never dared to deny that the purely Slav ancestry of the princely families and of most of the aristocratic families is beyond doubt. Queen Louisa of Prussia, whom all German nation­alists consider as the paragon of German womanhood, was a scion of the ruling house of Mecklenburg, whose originally Slav character has never been contested. Many noble families of the German Northeast can be traced back to Slav ancestors. The genealogical trees of the families of the middle classes and of the peasantry cannot be established as far back as those of the nobility; this alone explains why the proof of Slav origin can­not be provided for them.

    Shifting from one of these linguistic groups to another occurred not only in earlier days. It happened in the 19th century and today is so frequent that nobody ever remarks upon it. Many outstanding personalities in the Nazi movement in Germany and Austria and in the Czechoslovakian, Polish and Hungarian districts claimed by Nazism were the sons of parents whose language was not the German one." Similar conditions prevail in the nationalist parties of all East European linguistic groups. In many cases the change of loyalties was accompanied by a change of the family name. But many radical nationalists have retained their foreign sounding family names which clearly show their alien origin.

    Whenever the question is raised whether a group has to be considered as a distinct nation and should therefore as such be entitled to claim political autonomy; the issue is whether the idiom involved has to be considered as a distinct language or as a dialect only. The Russians maintain that the Ukrainian idiom is a dialect only, like the Plattdeutsch in Northern Germany or the Provencal of the felibrists in Southern France. The Czechs propose the same argument against the political aspirations of the Slovaks and the Italians against the Rhaeto-Romanic idiom. (Only a few years ago the Swiss government gave to the Romansh the legal status of a national language.)

    There is only one case in Eastern Europe where the characteristic feature which separates two nations is not language but religion and the alphabetical types used in writing and printing. The Serbs and the Croats speak the same language, but whereas the Serbs use the Cyrillic alphabet, the Croats use the Roman. The Serbs adhere to the orthodox creed of the Oriental Church, the Croats are Catholics.

    Religious issues, moreover, play only a subordinate role in these struggles of linguistic groups. It is, on the contrary, the linguistic issue which dominates religion. As soon as a linguistic group of the Oriental Church succeeded in obtaining some degree of political or cultural autonomy it freed itself from the religious rule of the patriarch of Constantinople and founded an autonomous church. No dogmatical differences motivated these changes; they were purely political.

    At the turn of the 16th and 17th centuries Ukrainian bishops acknowledged the Pope's supremacy. This Uniat Oriental Church was the main instrument in the poor Ukrainian serfs' fight against their oppressors. When Russia conquered the greater part of the Ukraine it violently persecuted this church in order to break the Ukrainian resistance against Russification. Finally the Czars succeeded in ex­terminating the Uniat Church on Russian soil. This church survived only in those parts of the country which were under the rule of the Hapsburgs.

    All those parts of Eastern Europe, which in the middle ages acknowledged the supremacy of the Pope, were some hundreds of years ago terribily shaken by religious struggles. But times have changed. Today Catholics and Protestants of different denominations jointly cooperate within each linguistic group. Loyalty to the nation means for them more than the community or religion.

    Only a few words have to be devoted to the Panslavist idea. The Russian governments — both that of the Czars and that of the Soviets — favored, at different times, a doctrine which assigned to the Russians, as the most numerous Slav nation, the task of freeing all Slav brethren from the yoke of the Germans, the Turks, the Italians and the Hungarians. As far as Panslavism means more — namely, the establishment of a unitary state including all Slav peoples under Russian hegemony — it was nothing else than a poor disguise for Russian imperialism. The Poles and the Ukrainians, who both knew what Russian rule meant, always opposed it bitterly. Neither are the other Slav peoples ready to surrender to Russia.

    Nowadays some authors recommend a Union of all Slavs as the best solution of the problems of Eastern Europe. Such a union would mean an alliance of the Slavs for the sake of the oppression of the Germans, Lithuanians, Estonians, Letts, Hungarians, Rumanians, Italians and Greeks living in Eastern Europe. It would not abolish, but perpetuate the struggles.

    IV. Present-day Conditions in Eastern Europe

    If you ask representatives of the nations of the European East what they consider would be a fair determination of the boundaries of their own countries and if you mark these boundaries on a map, then you will discover that the greater part of this territory is claimed by two nations and that a not negligible part is claimed by three nations. Every nation knows how to justify its claims with linguistic, racial, historical, geographical, economic, social or religious arguments. No nation is prepared to renounce the least of its claims for reasons of expediency. Every nation is ready to resort to arms in order to satis­fy its pretensions. Every nation, therefore, considers its immediate neighbors as mortal enemies and relies on its neighbors' neighbors for armed support of its own territorial claims against the common foe. Every nation tries to profit from every opportunity to satisfy its claims at the expense of its neighbors. The history of the last twenty years proves the correctness of this description.

    These claims are not claims of the governments or of "ruling" and "exploiting" classes, as current opinion would have us believe; these are claims of the whole nations and of every member of the respective linguistic groups. The governments are sometimes prepared to renounce some of these claims temporarily, in order to adjust the conduct of foreign policy to immediate political necessity.

    The wealthy classes are peace loving, because they do not want to suffer material losses. The radical nationalists, supported by the general consent of the large majorities, rebuke the governments for their cowardice and moderation and the capitalists and entrepreneurs for their selfish materialism. Extreme nationalism is not the work of bribed propagandists; it is a mentality created by the teachings and writings of sincere poets, writers and scholars. The teachers and the youth are the most enthusiastic supporters of chauvinism and nationalism. The nationalism of public opinion is intractable and intransigent and eliminates from the public scene every politician and every party suspected of being lenient in "national" concerns. The most radical na­tionalists terrorize the moderate men, because everybody knows that the voters favor the most radical program.

    Years ago it could be asserted that only the intellectuals were nationalists, whereas the uneducated masses were more or less indiffer­ent. This is no longer true since the spread of education has caused the disappearance of illiteracy. Besides in our age of economic inter­ventionism and its consequence — economic nationalism — every citizen has a personal interest in the result of these struggles between lin­guistic groups. Every peasant and every worker wishes that the area in which no discrimination is applied against him should be broadened. Every Czech shoe worker derived an immediate advantage from the fact that shoes manufactured in Czech plants could easily be sold in the sheltered markets of Slovakia and Carpatho-Russia. Every Croat peasant was injured by the fact that the Yugoslavian government's export agency dis­criminated against the Croats in purchasing cereals for sale to Germany. Austrian immigration barriers worked harm on all Czechs, Hungarians and Yugoslavs, who were barred from the Austrian labor market, where wages were higher than in their countries.

    It is impossible to draw boundaries in Eastern Europe which would clearly separate linguistic groups. A great part of this territory is linguistically mixed, i.e., inhabited, by men of different languages. Every territorial division would therefore necessarily leave minorities under foreign rule. These minorities are the bearers of permanent un­rest, of Irredentism and hatred.

    To dispose of the problem of minorities in a peaceful way two methods had been suggested.

    One method was the protection of minority rights by international law and its enforcement by international tribunals. The method failed. The economist has to recognize that such a system could be successfully applied only in a world of free trade and unhampered market economy. It must needs fail and it did fail in our age of economic intervention­ism. A law cannot protect anybody against measures dictated by alleged considerations of economic expediency. All measures of government in­terference in business can be and are used in countries inhabited by different linguistic groups for the sake of injuring the minorities. Customs tariffs, foreign exchange regulations, taxation, subsidies, labor legislation, and so on, may be utilized for discrimination al­though this cannot be proved in court procedure. The government can always explain such measures as being dictated by purely economic con­siderations. If licenses are denied to members of the minority but on the other hand are granted to the members of the privileged group the interference of an international tribunal is in vain. A system of foreign exchange regulation can be used to struggle all business activi­ties of the minority. By means of subsidies the minority has to contribute to the bounties paid to its competitors who belong to the ruling linguistic group. Where the export trade of agricultural produce is nationalized and a government agency is the only buyer on the export market, discrimination in making purchases and in prices paid is practiced against the minority. With the aid of government interfer­ence in business, life for the minorities without formal violation of legal equality can be made unbearable. In our age of interventionism there is no legal protection available against an ill-intentioned government.

    The impracticability of protecting minorities by international tribunals led to the proposal of another solution — the transplantation of minorities. This method could work only in a world in which all parts offered the same natural opportunities for production. In our actual world where the natural conditions for production are un­equally distributed, the execution of such a plan would only aggravate existing inequalities and therefore intensify the desire for territorial expansion. When Hitler withdrew some German minorities from the East, he did so because he believes that he has much more fertile land to offer them.

    The reform most commonly suggested recommends to these nations the formation of an economic union. An economic union would, under present conditions of government interference in business, have to in­clude a complete unification of all branches of economic policy. It would shift the political center of gravity to the executive office of the union and reduce the national governments to the level of provin­cial and local auxiliaries. We may witness today how in all federa­tions the power of the member states is gradually shrinking and that of the federal authorities increasing. This is not an accident. It is rather the unavoidable consequence of economic interventionism.

    The western nations are unjust when they ridicule the anarchic conditions in Eastern Europe and the inability of their rulers to find a way for peaceful neighborliness. These eastern nations do nothing else than imitate the economic policies of the western democracies. They apply the measures of economic nationalism. This means they dis­criminate against foreigners because they believe that in this way they can further the welfare of their own citizens. They have invented nothing; they have only taken over. It is not their fault that the contradictions and deficiencies of economic nationalism are more glar­ing under the conditions in which they have to live.

    There is general agreement today that the principle of unlimited sovereignty cannot be maintained in a world where the international division of labor results in a mutual dependence of every nation on all other nations. Notwithstanding this consensus nothing was done to limit the power of each nation, even the smallest one, to behave as if it were alone in the world. This contradiction is to be explained by the confusion which the term "limited sovereignty" involves. The con­cept of sovereignty, i.e., supreme power, does not allow for any limi­tation. A power may be supreme only if unlimited. If the power of a nation is limited so as to exclude some measures only, the remaining power can be used for the annihilation of this restriction. If, for instance, customs tariffs are excluded or limited it is possible to use other powers to render this limitation meaningless. It is possible, for example, to use the measures of veterinarian policy or measures for fighting plant diseases in a protectionist way, not to mention foreign exchange control and other methods. A pure limitation of sovereignty is not enough when the spirit of economic nationalism is allowed to survive. A total suppression of local sovereignty is necessary in order to insure good will and cooperation. To make Eastern Europe peaceful it is indispensable to vest the whole sovereignty in one democratic body ruling the entire area, which for more than 25 years has been a theatre of continual warfare and destruction.

    The world as a whole is not yet prepared to renounce national sovereignty in favor of a world government. The commonwealth of free nations and free men is today an utopian concept only. Great ide­ological changes have to take place until a mentality of universal peace and world-wide cooperation will have replaced the present-day spirit of conquest and mutual hatred.

    But Eastern Europe cannot wait any longer. Here something has to be done immediately. A return to the conditions of 1933 is out of the question. Conditions in which every sovereign state is looking for an opportunity to annex some territories belonging to its neighbors and every government considers a large number of its citizens as pariahs cannot be maintained.

    We may assume that every linguistic group is honest in believing that its own claims are better founded than those of the competing groups. But we cannot agree with the repeated assertions of some lin­guistic groups, that the yoke which they impose on other groups is more fair and reasonable and less hard than the yoke imposed on them by other linguistic groups. The judgment of the oppressed has not less weight than that of the oppressors. No linguistic group should be per­mitted to inflict harm on members of other groups. No "protectorate" can be considered as justified, if the "protected" do not want the alleged protection.

    We have to realize that the principle of nationality, as devel­oped in Western Europe, is simply inapplicable in Eastern Europe where the linguistic groups are inextricably mingled. The political system of Eastern Europe cannot therefore be built up as a replica of that in the West. New standards have to be applied.

    The foremost aim of a new order in Eastern Europe is to eliminate the problem of linguistic minorities. To be a member of such a lin­guistic minority means to be an outlaw. Every Slovak will say that this was the status of Slovaks in Hungary (before 1918) and in Czechoslovakia. (from 1918 to 1939); every Hungarian will say that this was the status of Hungarians in Czechoslovakia and is today in Slovakia; every Czech will say that this is today the status of Czechs both in those terri­tories which the Reich has annexed since 1939 and in the Protectorate. It is the same with all similar cases all over Eastern Europe. There were and are autonomy and democracy only for the members of the ruling linguistic majorities; the members of the minorities have the disadvan­tages but not the privileges of citizenship.

    It is immaterial to enter into a discussion of the claims of all these linguistic groups concerning their respective cultural values. It is of no concern whether or not the Hungarian civilization is higher than that of the Rumanians or of the Croats. The fact that Goethe, Kant and Beethoven were Germans does not justify the methods applied by the Nazis against the Czechs and the Poles; Mussolini may be right or wrong that Dante means more for humanity than Walter von der Vogelweide; but what relationship has this comparison of two poets to the problem of the oppression of the German-speaking inhabitants of Bozen and Brixen? It is grotesque that both Germans and Poles claim Copernicus for their own nation. It is beyond doubt that Copernicus wrote in Latin. There were in his time neither German nor Polish books on mathematics and astronomy; all the lectures which were de­livered at the Italian, German and Polish universities were delivered in Latin.

    We do not have to discuss the question whether it is of any value for mankind that the Czech, the Polish, the Ukrainian or the Serb civilizations should survive. The only fact which we have to face is this: there are people who wish to use freely the language which their parents have taught them. This legitimate desire has to be satisfied.

    It is not true that in order to develop its own civilization a linguistic group needs a government whose sovereignty can be used to inflict harm on other linguistic groups. No Hungarian can derive any advantage from the fact that to a Slovak or a Rumanian the right to use his native tongue is denied.

    The treaties of 1919 brought large minorities of Germans, Russians and Ukrainians under the rule of Czech and Polish majorities. This state of things could not be maintained except by a power strong enough to prevent both the Reich and the Soviet Union from interfering. It was based on the readiness of the French and the British to fight for the Czechs and the Poles.

    Of course, neither Germany nor Russia has a right to oppress the Poles or the Czechs. But their title is no worse than the title of the Czechs against the Germans in the districts of Eger and Reichenberg or of the Poles against the Ukrainians in Eastern Galicia.

    We do not mention these deplorable events of the past in order to blame anybody or in order to discover some nation's guilt. It is imma­terial to establish who the first aggressors were. It is without any consequence whether Bohemia in the early Middle Ages was inhabited by Germans or Slavs or whether the Germans came to Bohemia only in the late Middle Ages as colonists. An argument like that between Hungarian and Rumanian scholars concerning the question of whether the Rumanian settlement in Transylvania took place earlier or later is futile. It is useless to inquire whether the century-old hatred between Poles and Russians was inaugurated by Polish or by Russian aggression. Let by­gones be bygones. We do not have to revenge crimes of the past, but to build up a future, where people can enjoy the blessings both of peace and freedom.

    V. The Requisites for a Permanent Settlement of the East European Problem

    In order to make Eastern Europe safe for peace it is necessary to establish a state of things where war does not pay. The average citizen should not expect any profit from a war in which his own linguistic group would be victorious over one of the other linguistic groups. Within this area borderlines must lose their present meaning. They must not have more importance, in the future, than the frontiers between the 48 states of the United States of America or between the counties of England.

    The whole territory of Eastern Europe has to be organized as a political unit under a strictly unitary government. Within this whole area every individual has to have the right to choose the place where he wishes to live and to work. The laws and the authorities have to treat all natives — i.e., all citizens of Eastern Europe — in the same way on an equal footing without privileges or discrimination against individuals or groups.

    Within the frame of this new political structure — let us call it the Eastern Democratic Union (EDU) — the old political units may continue to function. A dislocation of the historically developed en­tities is not required. Once the problem of borders has been deprived of its disastrous political implications most of the existing national bodies can remain intact. Having lost their power to inflict evils on their neighbors and on their minorities, they may prove very useful for the progress of civilization and welfare.

    There will be, for instance, a Kingdom of Rumania and a Polish Republic. But these former sovereign states will now have to comply strictly with the laws and with the administrative provisions of the EDU. There will be no constitutional limit to the power of the EDU which could be used by an ill-intentioned local government to frustrate the laws and regulations issued by the EDU.

    This shows us why the aims of the EDU cannot be realized in the constitutional form of a federation (Bundes-staat). Under a federative system the constitution assigns some branches of government activity to the federal government and other branches to the local governments of the member states. As long as the constitution remains unchanged the federal government does not have the power to interfere with ques­tions which are in the jurisdiction of the member states. Such a sys­tem can succeed and has succeeded only with homogeneous peoples, where there exists a strong feeling of national unity and where no linguistic, religious, or racial discrepancies divide the population.

    Let us assume that the constitution of a supposed East European Federation grants to every linguistic group the right to establish schools, where its own language is taught. Then it would be illegal for a member state to hinder directly and openly the establishment of such schools. But if the building code and the administration of pub­lic health and firefighting are in the exclusive jurisdiction of the member states, a local government could use its powers to close the school on the ground that the building does not comply with the require­ments fixed by these regulations. The federal authorities would be helpless because they would not have the right to interfere, even if the grounds given prove to be only a subterfuge. Every kind of con­stitutional prerogative granted to the member states could be abused by a local government. If the fight against crime should be assigned to the member states, they could be slow in protecting the members of a minority group. If they should have the right to establish foreign exchange control they could discriminate against the members of the minority groups in complying with the demands for foreign exchange.

    If we want to abolish all discrimination against minority groups, if we want to give to all citizens actual and not only formal equality, we have to vest all powers in the central government only. This would not cripple the right of a loyal local government eager to use its powers in a fair way. But it would hinder the return to methods whereby the whole administrative apparatus of the government is used to inflict harm on minorities.

    A federation in Eastern Europe could never succeed in abolishing the political implications of the frontiers. In every member state there would remain the problem of minorities. There would be oppres­sion of minorities, hatred and irrenditism. The government of every member state would continue to consider its neighbors as adversaries. The diplomatic and consular agents of the three big adjacent powers would try to profit from these quarrels and rivalries and might succeed in disrupting the whole system.

    The main objectives of the new political order which has to be established in Eastern Europe are:

    1. This new system of government has to grant to every citizen full opportunity to live and to work freely without being molested by the hostility of any linguistic group inside or outside the boundaries of Eastern Europe. Nobody should be prosecuted or disqualified on ac­count of his mother tongue or his creed. Every linguistic group should have the right to use its own language. No discrimination should be tolerated against minority groups and its members. Every citizen should be treated in such a way that he will call the country without any reservation "my country" and the government "our government."

    2. No linguistic group should expect any improvement of its political status by a change in the territorial organization. The dif­ference between a ruling linguistic group and oppressed linguistic minorities has to disappear. There must not be any "Irrendenta."

    3. The system has to be strong enough to defend its independence against aggression on the part of its neighbors. Its armed forces have to be able to repel without foreign assistance an isolated aggression of either Germany or Italy or Russia. It should rely on the help of the Western democracies only against a common aggression by at least two of these neighbors.

    VI. The Abandonment of Economic Nationalism

    The EDU will have to renounce all hostility against any linguistic group. This includes the elimination of all measures of economic na­tionalism. Economic nationalism is, as already mentioned, a policy which intends to improve the conditions of some groups of citizens by inflicting evils on foreigners; it is a policy of discrimination against foreigners. Foreign goods are excluded from the domestic market or only permitted after having paid an import duty. Foreign labor is disbarred from competition on the domestic labor market. Foreign capital is liable to confiscation. But all these measures hurt at the same time the economic interests of some groups of citizens. An import duty for shoes, for instance, may benefit the people interested in this par­ticular branch of industry, but it injures all consumers of shoes.

    It was feasible in linguistically homogeneous nations to justify import duties in the eyes of the consumers. The German protectionists, for instance, succeeded in convincing the majority of the German voters that it is expedient for them to pay a much higher price than the world market price for wheat in order to increase the revenue of the German wheat producers. But in a country inhabited by different linguistic groups such a justification would not be considered as satisfactory. Those linguistic groups whose industrial production is backward will never acquiesce to an import duty for shoes which would benefit the shoe production of those linguistic groups whose industrial production has reached a higher stage of development. They will call such foreign trade policy an exploitation of their own group. The history of the Austro-Hungarian customs union provides us with ample evidence for the correctness of this statement. Sometimes even within linguistically homogeneous nations the discussion concerning the foreign trade policy favors the spirit of disintegration. Both in the Dominion of Canada and in the Commonwealth of Australia the purely agricultural western parts oppose the protectionist policy of the more industrialized sec­tions and even ventured to propose a dissolution of the customs union.

    If the EDU would embark on a policy of protectionism its existence would be doomed.

    The EDU will therefore be a country of free trade. There will be no protective tariffs nor other measures for the protection of home industries against foreign competition. There will be neither foreign exchange control nor inflationary measures. There will be neither subsidies nor bounties and no migration barriers. There will be a stable currency system with stable rates of foreign exchange.

    All objections raised against such a policy of free trade on the part of a single country within a world of economic nationalism and pro­tectionism are futile. It would be a waste of time to refute again the popular fallacy that such a country would not be able to continue any domestic production and only import from abroad.

    The far greater part of Eastern Europe is mostly interested in the export of food and raw material. These agricultural, forest, and mining interests cannot suffer any disadvantage from a policy of free trade. On the other hand, it is obvious that none of the industrial in­terests of this territory can assume that the excessive protectionism of the past could be continued even if the EDU should not be formed.

    Let us consider the two types of foreign trade policy applied in this territory before 1938 in referring to Austria as an instance of agricultural protectionism and to Hungary as an instance of industrial protectionism.

    In Austria the non-agricultural section of the population was ex­ploited for the benefit of agriculture. Food prices in Austria were maintained at a level of much more than 200 percent of world market prices. The peasants got from the treasury much more as bounties than they had to pay as taxes. In the mountain districts the peasants got a premium for tilling the land regardless of whether climatic conditions will allow the corn to ripen. For butter the government, paradoxically enough, paid export subsidies, which were much higher than the world market price of butter. It will be impossible to continue these methods after the war to the disadvantage of the impoverished non-agricultural population.

    Hungary on the other hand exploited the agricultural population for the benefit of industrial production. The prices of manufactured goods were much higher than in the world market and in the countries of Western Europe and America. A system of more or less concealed export premiums and tax exemptions furthered the export of manufactured goods which were unavailable to the masses of peasants and poor agricultural workers. It is obvious that such a policy will have to be abandoned sooner or later.

    The main economic problem which the peoples of Eastern Europe have to face is relative overpopulation. In respect to the natural conditions which this territory offers for production and in respect to the density of population in areas much better endowed by nature all these countries are overpopulated. The abolition of migration barriers in other parts of the world would result in an emigration of scores of millions from Eastern Europe and would create a tendency towards an equalization of the marginal productivity of labor; wages and farmers' income in Eastern Europe would rise. (Of course, the tilling of the poorer soil would be discontinued.) Migration barriers force these peoples to stay at home and put a check on the improvement of their standard of living. But this problem cannot be solved by any scheme limited to the domestic organization of Eastern Europe. It is a world problem.

    The second economic problem of these countries is scarcity of capital. It is unlikely that foreign capital will be available for them. Private investors will have more promising offers for the employ­ment of their funds; foreign governments will consider domestic invest­ment as more useful than the export of capital to Eastern Europe.

    Even with a smoothly functioning political organization Eastern Europe will remain a poor country with a standard of life which Americans and Britons will judge as a very low one.

    But all these sad facts cannot be considered as valid objections against the scheme proposed. There is no other method left for Eastern Europe to improve its economic conditions than the establishment of a durable peace and the abandonment of the policies which wasted the eco­nomic resources and the capital accumulated in previous years.

    VII. Outlines of the New Order

    1. The Area of the EDU

    The EDU has to include the territories which in 1933 formed the sovereign states of Albania, Austria, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Danzig, Estonia, Greece, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Rumania and Jugoslavia.

    It has to include the whole territory which in 1913 belonged to the Prussian provinces — Eastern Prussia, Western Prussia, Posen and Silesia. The three first-named provinces were once parts of Poland. They were appropriated by the princes of the House of Hohenzollern, but this conquest did not make them a part of the Holy Roman Empire. The fact that the rulers of these countries were at the same time Electors of Brandenburg had legally and constitutionally no other significance than the fact that the kings of England were Electors (and later kings) of Hanover. Neither did these provinces belong to the German Confedera­tion from 1815–1866. They remained "private property" of the Hohen­zollern family. Only after the battle of Koniggrätz in 1866 the king of Prussia incorporated them by his own sovereign decision into the Norddeutscher Bund and later in 1871 into the Deutsches Reich.

    Silesia was a part of the Holy Roman Empire only as an adjunct of the Kingdom of Bohemia. In the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries it was ruled by dukes who belonged to a branch of the Piasts, the old royal family of Poland. When Frederick the Great in 1740 embarked on the con­quest of Silesia he tried to justify his claims by pointing out that he was the legitimate heir of the Piast family.

    All these four provinces are inhabited by a linguistically mixed population. They returned many Polish members to the old German Reichstag. In Eastern Prussia there is a not negligible Lithuanian minority.

    Italy has to cede to the EDU all the European countries which it has occupied since 1913, the Dodecanese Islands and the eastern part of the province of Venice, Friuli, a district inhabited by people speaking a Rhaeto-Romanic idiom.

    Thus the EDU will include about 700,000 square miles with about 120,000,000 people using 17 different languages. Such a country when united will be strong enough to defend its independence against the three mighty neighbors, Russia, Germany and Italy.

    2. The Constitution

    Every adult will have the right to vote. The parliament — one chamber only, with about 600 members — has to be a fair representation of all citizens. The cabinet has to be responsible to the parliament.

    The parliament's first task will be to make a constitution. It will decide whether the head of the EDU should be a President or a hereditary ruler.

    The parliament will be the only legislative body. All local and provincial councils will be advisory boards only. Every attempt to give more power to provincial institutions and to local boards would neces­sarily revive the problems of borders and of minorities.

    3. Local Government

    The former independent states will in the framework of the EDU be nothing else than provinces. Retaining all their honorary forms they will have to comply strictly with the laws and with the administrative provisions of the EDU. But so long as they do not try to violate these laws and regulations they will be free. The loyal and law-abiding gov­ernment of each state will not be hindered, but strongly supported by the central government.

    Special commissaries of the EDU will have to oversee the function­ing of every local government. Against all administrative acts of the local authorities the parties will have the right to appeal to this commissary, and to the central government, provided that such acts are not liable to be appealed to a tribunal. All disagreements between the commissary and the local government or between different local govern­ments will be ultimately adjudicated by the central government, which is responsible to the central parliament only. The supremacy of the central government will not be limited by any constitutional preroga­tives of local authorities. Disagreements will be settled by the central government and by the central parliament, which will judge and decide every problem in the light of its implications for the smooth working of the total system. If, for instance, there arises a dispute concern­ing questions of the City of Wilno — one of the innumerable neuralgic points of the East — the solution will be sought not only between the Polish and the Lithuanian local governments or between the Polish and Lithuanian members of the central parliament; the central government and the central parliament will try to find a solution which will do justice to similar cases arising in Budweis, in Temesvar or in Salonica.

    In this way it may be possible to have a unitary government with a high degree of administrative decentralization.

    4. The Budget and the Power to Tax

    All financial powers will be vested in the central government and in the central parliament.

    The parliament will allocate to every local government for its expenditures a lump sun according to the population of its area. It will, ­in addition, supervise the spending of this money.

    It is further advisable to give to every local government the revenue derived from taxes on real estate situated in its jurisdiction. But in any case the laws regulating these taxes have to be enacted by the central parliament.

    With regard to provisions for government bonds issued prior to the establishment of the new order an international agreement between the EDU and the representatives of the foreign bondholders will be necessary. New loans will be floated only by the central government or, with its permission, by the bigger cities.

    5. The Linguistic Problem

    The most delicate problem of the EDU will be the linguistic problem.

    All the 17 languages will be treated in an equal way. In every district, county, or community the tribunals, the government agencies and the municipalities will have to use all languages which in their district, county or community are the languages of more than 20 percent of the population.

    English has to be used as an international subsidiary language for the dealings between the members of different linguistic groups. All laws have to be published in English and in all 17 national idioms. This system may seem strange and very complicated. But we have to realize that it worked rather satisfactorily in old Austria with 8 languages. Contrary to a widespread error the German language had no constitutional preeminence in imperial Austria.

    6. Religion

    The peaceful coexistence of different denominations can easily be secured by the adoption of the system which has succeeded in the United States of America.

    7. Education

    The governments of Eastern Europe abused the system of compulsory education in order to force the minorities to give up their own languages and to adopt the language of the majority. The EDU will have to be strictly neutral in this respect.

    There will be private schools only. Every citizen and every group of citizens will have the right to run educational institutions. If these schools comply with the standards fixed by the central government they are subsidized by a lump sum for every pupil.

    The curriculum of the secondary education will include the teach­ing of English.

    The local governments will have the right to take over the adminis­tration of some schools. But even in this case the budget of these schools has to be kept independent of the general budget of the local government and no public funds but those allocated by the central government as subsidies for these schools may be used.

    8. Economic Policy

    It is necessary to deny to the government the power to benefit one linguistic group at the expense of others. There will be neither subsidies nor licenses which can be granted or denied ad libitum.

    To the general principle that no measures of protectionism should be applied one exception only should be permitted. The importation of commodities from countries which do not treat the imports from the EDU according to the most favored nation standard or do not allow any imports at all may be prohibited or taxed.

    9. Measure for the Period of Transition

    The first president and the members of the first cabinet have to be appointed by the League of Nations. They will have to hand over their functions to the parliament as soon as it is constituted.

    For a period of transition foreign citizens — with the exception of Germans, Italians, Russians and the subjects of totalitarian states will be eligible for all public and judiciary offices and functions.

    10. Working of the System

    A foreign visitor, more interested in sightseeing than in the study of constitutional and economic problems, will notice the disappearance of the customs barriers and of the variety of national currency systems, but in all other respects it will be impossible for him to ob­serve any change. He will say, "Now I have visited Hungary and I want to go to Rumania." He will not see the EDU; he will not have the op­portunity to meet the agents of the EDU.

    There will be the old national flags and anthems. Every member state will have its own postage stamps issued by the unitary postal sys­tem of the EDU. There will be coins of every member state, coined with the national emblems and — in monarchies — with the portrait of the king (as in the German Reich from 1873 until 1914). Of course all these coins will be minted by order of the EDU's government and will be legal tender in the whole territory of the EDU. Every member state and every linguistic group will be free to cultivate intellectual relations with foreign countries and to represent its own civilization abroad.

    The individual citizen will have to renounce all claims for privi­leges which could harm other individuals or groups. But he will be free to use his own mother tongue and to bring up his children with the aid of schools where this language is taught. He will not have to consider himself as a citizen of minor status, because all authorities and tri­bunals will treat him in a fair way.

    VIII. The Political Chances of the Proposed Plan

    We have to realize that the politicians and the statesmen of these eastern nations are united today on only one point: the rejection of such a proposal. They do not see that the only other alternative is the partition of their territories among Germany, Russia and Italy. They do not see it because they firmly rely on the invincibility of the British and the American forces. They do not imagine that the Americans and the British have any other task in this world than to fight for them an endless sequence of world wars.

    It would be merely an evasion of reality if the refugee representa­tives of these nations would try to convince us that they have the in­tention of peacefully disposing of their mutual claims in the future. It is true that the Polish and the Czech refugees have made an agree­ment concerning the delimitation of the boundaries and a future politi­cal cooperation. But this scheme will not work when actually put into practice. We have ample experience that all agreements of this type fail because the radical nationalists never accept them. All endeavors at an understanding between Germans and Czechs in old Austria met with disaster because the fanatical youth rejected what the more realistic older leaders had proposed. Refugees are, of course, more ready to compromise than men in power. During the First World War the Czechs and the Slovaks and likewise the Serbs, the Croats and the Slovenes came to an understanding in exile. History has proved the futility of these alleged agreements.

    Besides that, we have to realize that the area which is claimed both by the Czechs and by the Poles is comparatively small and of minor importance for each group. There is no hope that a similar agreement ever could be effected between the Poles on the one hand and the Germans, the Lithuanians, the Russians or the Ukrainians on the other hand — or between the Czechs on the one hand and the Germans or the Hungarians or the Slovaks on the other hand.

    What is needed is not delimitation of specific borderlines between two groups but a system where the drawing of borderlines no longer creates disaffection among minorities, unrest and irredentism.

    Democracy can be maintained in the East only by an impartial gov­ernment. Within the EDU no single linguistic group will be sufficiently numerous to dominate the rest. The most numerous linguistic group will be the Poles; they will comprise about 20 percent of its whole population.

    It is not unlikely that some critics will call the EDU a recon­struction of the old Austrian empire on a broader scale. This is true as far as old Austria (but not Hungary!) was the only power among those ruling in this area which tried to treat all citizens on an equal foot­ing. In the Turkish empire all Christians were pariahs. In Russia, Prussia, and Hungary the governments were eager to force all subjects to give up their mother-tongues and to become Russians, German-speaking Prussians, or Magyars. In Austria the constitution of 1867 granted to every citi­zen the right to use his own language and provided equality in the use of all languages in court procedure, in the administration, and in edu­cational institutions. The system failed, because the striving for full national independence of every linguistic group hindered its success. Some details of the suggested constitution for the EDU are based on precisely the lessons which this Austrian failure teaches us and at the same time on the shortcomings of the League of Nations minority pro­tection.

    There is no other precedent which we could use in framing a new political system for Eastern Europe. The Swiss Confederation cannot be considered as a useful pattern. In Switzerland the cooperation of the three (or four) linguistic groups was undisturbed as long as its eco­nomic policy was based on free trade. With the trend towards economic interventionism conditions changed. Today there is a not negligible Nazi party in the German-speaking cantons and a powerful pro-Fascist group in the Ticino. The French-speaking cantons strongly oppose what they call the policy of Berne. Switzerland will have to face serious problems in a not too distant future.

    There was still another linguistically mixed democratic country in Europe, Belgium. Here too the linguistic diversion disrupted the political unity. The military defeat of Belgium was to a great extent due to the irrendentism of the Vlames. Belgium will have to solve its linguistic problem in the future.

    We do not have to discuss in this context the general problem of government interference with business. It suffices to realize the fact that the system of interventionism can never work satisfactorily where different linguistic groups are determined to use it as a weapon in their wars aiming at mutual extermination.

    More serious would be the objection that the territory assigned to the EDU is too large and that the different linguistic groups in­volved have nothing in common. It seems indeed strange that the Lithuanians should have to cooperate with the Greeks although they never before had had any other mutual relations than those diplomatic ones existing among all nations of the world.

    But we have to realize that the EDU has to create peace in a part of the world ridden by age-old struggles among linguistic groups. Within the whole area assigned to the EDU there cannot be discovered any un­disputed borderline. If the EDU has to include both the Lithuanians and the Poles, because there is a large area where Poles and Lithuanians live inextricably mixed and which both nations vigorously claim for themselves, it has to include the Czechs and the Ukrainians too because the same conditions as between the Poles and the Lithuanians prevail between the Poles and the Czechs and between the Poles and the Ukrainians. Then the Hungarians have to be included for the same reasons, next the Serbs and consequently all other nations which claim parts of the terri­tory known as Macedonia, i.e., the Bulgarians, the Albanians and the Greeks.

    For the smooth functioning of the EDU it is not required that the Greeks should consider the Lithuanians as friends and brothers. (Although it seems probable that they would have more friendly feelings for them than for their immediate neighbors.) What is needed is nothing else than the conviction of the politicians of all these peoples that it is no longer possible to oppress men who happen to speak a foreign language. They do not have to love one another but to stop inflicting harm on one another.

    The EDU will include many millions of German-speaking citizens and some hundreds of thousands of Italian-speaking citizens. It cannot be denied that the hatred engendered by the methods used by the Nazis and the Fascists during the present war will not disappear at once. It will be difficult for Poles and Czechs to meet for collaboration with Germans.

    But none of these objections can be considered as valid. There is no other solution for the East European problem which could give to these nations a life of peace and political independence.

    Conclusion

    The third point of the Atlantic Declaration establishes as a common principle in the national policies both of the United States and of the British Empire that "they respect the right of all peoples to choose the form of government under which they will live; and they wish to see sovereign rights and self-government restored to those who have been forcibly deprived of them." The sixth point expresses the "hope to see established a peace which will afford to all nations the means of dwelling safely within their own boundaries, and which will afford assurance that all the men in all the lands may live out their lives in freedom from fear and want."

    These principles are incompatible with the conditions which have prevailed for ages in Eastern Europe. There were many millions of people who were forced to live under governments which they had not chosen. There were countries where 20 percent, 30 percent or even 40 percent of the population were irredentists and expected to be redeemed by the armed interference of foreign powers. These millions considered themselves as having been forcibly deprived of their sovereign rights and self-government. They believed that they were prevented from liv­ing out their lives in freedom from fear and want.

    The proposed scheme for an Eastern Democratic Union is the only plan which could adjust political and economic conditions in Eastern Europe to the requirements of the Atlantic Declaration. Its execution would impose on no nation any other sacrifice than the renunciation of the power to inflict harm on other linguistic groups. But it would on the other hand secure them against the risk of falling victim to oppres­sion by other nations. It would make Eastern Europe safe both for peace and democracy.

    Why Is the Euro Still Gaining Against the Dollar?

    Why Is the Euro Still Gaining Against the Dollar?

    The primary purposes of the incorrectly named “unconventional monetary policies” are to debase the currency, stoke inflation, and make exports more competitive. Printing money aims to solve structural imbalances by making currencies weaker.

    In this race to zero in global currency wars, central banks today are “printing” more than $200 billion per month despite that the financial crisis passed a long time ago.

    Currency wars are those that no one admits to waging, but everyone wants to fight in secret. The goal is to promote exports at the expense of trading partners.

    Reality shows currency wars do not work, as imports become more expensive and other open economies become more competitive through technology. But central banks still like weak currencies — they help to avoid hard reform choices and create a transfer of wealth from savers to debtors.

    The Euro Rallies

    So how must the bureaucrats at the European Central Bank (ECB) feel when they see the euro rise against the U.S. dollar and all its main trading currencies by more than 12 percent in a year, despite all the talk about more easing? The ECB will keep buying 60 billion euro a month in bonds, maintain its zero interest-rate policy, and keep this “stimulus” as long as it takes, until inflation growth and GDP growth are stable.

    Contrary to the wishes of the ECB, however, a strong euro is justified for several reasons. First, the European Union’s trade surplus is at record highs, and 75 percent of Eurozone trade happens between eurozone countries. Higher exports and the continued recovery of internal demand in European member countries strengthen the euro.

    The third is the perception of weakness of the U.S. government and its inability to push through key reforms. This has weakened the dollar and by definition strengthened the other two large trading currencies, the euro and the Japanese yen.The second important factor is the relief rally after the French and Dutch elections. The fears of a euro breakup have been eliminated, or at least delayed, as pro-EU political parties won.

    The Problems With a Strong Euro

    However, a strong euro has very significant implications for the EU economy and the ECB’s policy.

    The strong euro puts exports to its main outside trading partners — the United States (20.8 percent of exports in 2016) and China (9.7 percent) — at risk. Despite the ECB’s extreme monetary policy and a euro trading almost at parity with the dollar, exports to non-EU countries have stalled since 2013. GDP growth estimates for 2018 are falling due to a lower contribution of net exports.

    The currency also has a high impact on tax revenues in Europe. The correlation between the euro–dollar exchange rate and the earnings estimates of the largest multinationals represented in the Stoxx Europe 600 Index is very high.

    According to our estimates, a 10 percent rise of the euro against the dollar is equivalent to an 8 percent drop in earnings and leads to lower corporate tax revenues. From an investment perspective, as earnings drop, the European stock market goes from being relatively cheaper to becoming more expensive.

    Investors and economists need to pay attention to these factors. If the euro continues to strengthen, the EU economic recovery is at risk. So the eurozone is stuck between a rock and a hard place. It cannot stop the stimulus because deficit spending governments cannot live with higher financing costs, and increasing the stimulus to weaken the currency simply doesn’t work anymore.

    The only way out is structural reforms, but most governments are afraid of them even in good times, let alone when the going gets tough.

    Originally published by Epoch Times. Reprinted with permission. 

    Mises Wire
    enSeptember 13, 2017

    Stanley Fischer’s Well-Timed Fed Exit

    Stanley Fischer’s Well-Timed Fed Exit

    Fed vice-chair Stanley Fischer’s surprise announcement of early retirement triggers the obvious question as to whether this could be the fore-runner to a serious market and economic deterioration ahead. Monetary bureaucrats, even if signally bad at counter-cyclical fine tuning, sometimes have a reputation for intuition about how to time their own career moves ahead of crisis. In this case, such suspicion may be wide of the mark given the personal circumstances. Even so, the exit of a Fed Vice-Chair, who in many respects has been the pioneer and the dean of the prevailing doctrine in the global central bankers club, is pause for thought.

    The Early Years

    When Professor Fischer published his famous paper “On Activist Monetary Policy with Rational Expectations” (NBER working paper no. 341, April 1979), the fiat money world was well into the third stage of disorder following the collapse of the international gold standard in 1914. But things were at a temporary resting point where the skies seemed to be getting clearer. After the violent terminal storms of the gold exchange standard (early 20s to early 30s), and then of the Bretton Woods System, it seemed to many that the “monetarist revolutionaries” had found a better practical monetary navigation route. The Bundesbank, the Federal Reserve, the Swiss National Bank, and even the Bank of Japan were pursuing an ersatz gold rule of low percentage increases in the monetary base or a related aggregate.

    Fischer vs. the Monetarists

    Despite the optimism at large, Fischer issued a challenge. The monetarist rules (x per cent growth of the chosen monetary aggregate) were doomed to fail when the underlying demand for money and monetary base in particular was so unstable.

    Fischer rejected the new popular view (in the late 1970s) of the fashionable “classical economists” (for example Robert Barro) who argued that under market rationality monetary policy was powerless to influence the real economy. All the various trade-offs hypothesized by the Keynesian economists of the previous decade and pursued in part had been based on a view that central bankers could take the public by surprise (who would not realize what they were “up to” until later on). But once the public knew all Keynesian manipulations could not be effective.

    In contrast, Fischer purported to demonstrate that if wages were rigid (most likely due to the existence of long-term contracts), then even given rational expectations, monetary policy could stimulate the real economy.

    And so Professor Fischer, on the basis of his pioneering neo-Keynesian creed, preached that, yes, central bankers could and should pursue activist contra-cyclical strategies, especially when shocks were large and obvious. But yes, he also recognized that fine-tuning had its dangers and could morph into a long-run rising inflation rate, and so he recommended that policy be bound by the setting of a low inflation target. These ideas were in turn taken up and worked on by leading disciples (students) of Stanley Fischer, including Ben Bernanke and Mario Draghi.

    The Birth of the 2% Inflation Standard

    And so the fourth stage of fiat money disorder was born — what we may describe as the “global 2% inflation standard”. The prior monetarist experiments faded away in the decade following publication of Fischer’s paper (Paul Volcker abandoned monetarism by 1982, and the Bundesbank was the last hold-out in the year before the launch of the euro). At a stretch we could call this fourth stage the “Fischerian age of monetary policy”. Even though its author is now retiring, the outlook is for this stage to move eventually into a much more vicious sub-stage in which inflation rises far above the levels which the central bankers are purporting to target and the forces of rationality greeted by the classical revivalists have been completely trumped by powerful irrational forces which typify asset price inflation..

    And all of this does not depend on who exactly President Trump decides to nominate in Fischer’s and Yellen’s place in coming months, even though there are reasons to speculate that the choice is likely to be pro-3% growth with the near-term target of avoiding defeat in next year’s mid-term elections. The bigger issue is that the so-called 2% inflation target belongs to a collection of fables under the title of the Emperor’s New Clothes. In today’s monetary environment where monetary base has been totally dislocated from the pivot of the monetary system (e.g., there's no stable demand, distinctive qualities of base money are virtually eradicated, and both supply and demand are boated by QE) there is no basis – other than expectation inertia – to view prices of goods and services as anchored.

    At the best of times no one knew the precise relationship between monetary aggregates and prices — and indeed under the gold standard or monetarism no one pretended to have the price path under control; at best money was under control and that should foster some long-run tendency for prices to return to the mean, but there was no assurance of this. Strikingly the “Fischerians” have lost all sight of the natural rhythm of prices as responding to fluctuations in the pace of globalization, productivity growth, and of course the business cycle.

    There is every reason to believe that expectation inertia will snap at some point in the future. And the root combination of monetary disorder — a Federal budget deficit of 4-5-6% of GDP at a cyclical peak, a Federal Reserve determined to hold down rates and manage the government bond markets, an administration favoring a weak dollar — there are grounds for fearing a lurch of the monetary train towards high inflation, albeit possibly beyond the next business cycle trough. And all of that despite the pride of Stanley Fischer in his resignation letter to President Trump:

    During my time on the Board, the economy has continued to strengthen, providing millions of additional jobs for working Americans. Informed by the lessons of the recent financial ciris, we have buildt upon earlier steps to make the financial system stronger and more resilient and better able to provide the credit so vital to the prosperity of our country’s households and businesses.

    Power corrupts, and Washington corrupts absolutely. How can anyone pretend to have learnt the lessons and achieved the results until at least one long business cycle under the given monetary regime has been completed? Only then can all the mal-investment be counted and the financial quake or hurricane damage assessed.

    Mises Wire
    enSeptember 09, 2017

    Trump's Historic Opportunity with the Federal Reserve

    Trump's Historic Opportunity with the Federal Reserve

    And then there were three.

    Today Stanley Fischer submitted his letter of resignation from the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors, effective next month, the second such resignation of Donald Trump’s presidency. While Fischer’s term as Vice Chairman of the Fed was set to end next year, he had the ability to serve as a governor through 2020. Along with Trump’s decision next year on whether to replace Janet Yellen as the Fed’s chair, this means Trumps will have the opportunity to appoint five of seven governors to America’s central bank.

    Given that the position holds a 14-year term, it is unusual for a president to have the opportunity to make so many appointments. As Diane Swonk of DS Economics noted, “It’s the largest potential regime change in the leadership of the Fed since 1936.”

    Of course the question is now whether a change in personnel will lead to a change in policy.

    Trump has already taken steps to fill one of the vacancies, nominating Randal Quarles earlier this year. Quarles, a former Bush-era Treasury official turned investment banker, will be taking the specific role of Fed vice chair of supervision. As a vocal critic of Dodd-Frank, and the Volker Rule in particular, Quarles may help relieve some of the regulatory burden on financial institutions, but his views on monetary policy are less clear. He has also voiced his support for rules-based monetary policy, though he has distanced himself to the specific proposal of the “Taylor Rule.” Given the growing consensus building for NGDP-targeting, and Republicans in Congress advocating for rules-based Fed reform, Quarles could become a supporter from within the central bank. All in all though, Quarles is seen by many observes as a bland Fed-appointment.

    More concerning are the views of Marvin Goodfriend, who has been reported to be a front runner for one of the Fed vacancies. An economics professor at Carnegie Mellon University and former director of research at the Richmond Fed, Goodfriend has a traditional central banker background and the dangers that comes with it. In 2016, Goodfriend made an impassioned plea for the Fed to consider negative-interest rates:

    The zero interest bound is an encumbrance on monetary policy to be removed, much as the gold standard and the fixed foreign exchange rate encumbrances were removed, to free the price level from the destabilizing influence of a relative price over which monetary policy has little control—in this case, so movements in the intertemporal terms of trade can be reflected fully in interest rate policy to stabilize employment and inflation over the business cycle.

    Since negative interest rates usually coincide with greater use of cash (and personal vaults), Goodfriend went so far as to suggest the Fed should consider devaluing the value of printed bank notes. A $10 bill would buy less than a $10 debit card transaction, opening up a new front in the ongoing war on cash.  

    Given his radical views on monetary policy, it’s not hyperbole to suggest that Goodfriend’s nomination would represent a genuine danger to the economic wellbeing of every American citizen – or at least those outside of the financial services industry.

    Unfortunately, even if Goodfriend doesn’t get the nod, it’s unlikely Trump will nominate anyone who understands the negative consequences of our artificially low interest rate environment. Though Candidate Trump demonstrated remarkable savvy when it came to how the actions of Bernanke and Yellen hurt Americans, as President Trump he has consistently indicated a desire to keep the “big fat bubble” going. Such a desire obviously fits the self-interest of the White House, but with long-term consequences for the base that elected him.

    The only hope for a change in direction from the Administration is for Trump to stop listening to his Goldman Guys and instead lean on the team that helped get him to the White House. As Tommy Behkne noted last November, Trump had managed to surround himself with a number of Fed skeptics during his campaign, and even considered Austrian-friendly John Allison for Treasury Secretary.

    Given the historic opportunity he has with the Fed, if Trump chooses to return to those roots, he could do severe damage to the swamp — all without passing a single piece of legislation through Congress.

    Mises Wire
    enSeptember 07, 2017

    Stanley Fischer Is Out at the Fed

    Stanley Fischer Is Out at the Fed

    Fed Vice Chair and Yellen ally Stanely Fischer announced his unexpected resignation today, citing “personal reasons.” His term as a Fed governor wasn’t to be over until 2020 and his vice chairmanship was to end June of next year.

    Fischer was one of the three most important Fed members, the other two being Yellen herself and the New York Fed’s William Dudley. The WSJ reports:

    Mr. Fischer came to the Fed in 2014 a luminary in central banking, having taught many leading policy makers during a more-than two decade career as a professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology specializing in international economics. His students included European Central Bank President Mario Draghi and former Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke.

    Mr. Fischer also ran a central bank—the Bank of Israel—from 2005 to 2013, held a senior post at the International Monetary Fund and served as a Citigroup vice chairman.

    In terms of the insider status of these central bankers, Mr. Fischer was “Mr. Establishment.” Well educated in the machinations of how to control an economy from the top, Fischer was an expert bureaucrat. On paper, Fischer was among the most qualified in the world to be tasked with impossible role of making us more prosperous by diktat.

    In reality, Fischer, to the extent he had a marked influence on central bankers like Draghi, Bernanke, Yellen, and so many others, was a key player in the boom-and-bust system of modern monetary economics. Under his watch, we had two major and devastating recessions— the cause of which was not Fischer’s failure individually, but the inflationary framework that pervades them all.

    Fischer was considered to have leaned “hawkish” by the financial press. In the old days of Paul Volcker, a hawk was one wary of dangers of rising inflation. This was juxtaposed to a dove, who would downplay the dangers of inflation and advise greater monetary expansion. But in the post-crisis era of the so-called “new normal,” where interest rates are to remain absurdly low and inflation must be targeted at 2%, the hawks have long gone extinct. Fischer was no hawk, he was a cheerleader of the quadrupling of the Fed’s balance sheet, an advocate of unprecedented credit creation, and a hater of sound money.

    It remains to be seen where Fischer will go next. But his undying advocacy of the use of central banking to tinker with and manage the economy will live on.

    See also:

    "The Fed Wants to Test Drive Negative Interest Rates" by Joseph Salerno "Stanley Fischer's Eureka Moment" by C.Jay Engel

    Mario Draghi’s Fatal Conceit

    Mario Draghi’s Fatal Conceit

    On 23 August 2017, the president of the European Central Bank (ECB) gave a speech titled “Connecting research and policy making” at the annual assembly of the winners of the Nobel Price for Economics in Lindau, Germany.See Draghi, M., The interdependence of research and policymaking, speech at the Lindau Nobel Laureate Meeting, Lindau, Germany, 23 August 2017.  What Mr Draghi talked about on this occasion — and especially what he didn’t talk about — was quite revealing.

    Any analysis of the causes of the latest financial and economic crisis is conspicuously absent from Mr Draghi’s remarks. One gets the impression that the crisis came basically unexpected, out of the blue. There is no mention of the role of central banks, the monopoly producers of unbacked paper (or: fiat) money, played for the crisis.

    No word that central banks had for many years manipulated downwards interest rates — accompanied by an excessive increase in credit and money supply — causing an unsustainable “boom.” When the bust set in — triggered by the spreading of the US subprime crisis across the globe — the ugly consequences of this central bank monetary policy came to the surface.

    In the bust, many governments, banks and consumers in the euro area found themselves financially overstretched. The economies of Southern Europe especially do not only suffer from malinvestment on a grand scale, they also found themselves in a situation in which they have lost their competitiveness.

    Mr Draghi, however, doesn’t deal with such unpleasant details. Instead, he lets his audience know how well the ECB pursued a policy of "crisis solution." His narrative is straightforward: Without the ECB’s bold actions, the euro area would have fallen into recession-depression, perhaps the euro area would have broken apart.

    The analogy to such a line of argumentation would be praising a drug dealer, who provides the drug addict (who became a drug addict because of him) with just another shot. Repeated consumption of drugs does not heal but damages drug addict. Who would applaud what the drug dealer does? Likewise: would it be appropriate to praise the ECB’s action?

    Mr Draghi presents himself as a fairly modest, intellectually ‘undogmatic’ central bank president stressing the importance of the insights produced by economic research for real life monetary policy making (thereby dutifully applauding the output of the economics profession). But the policy maker’s approach is far from being scientifically impartial.

    Draghi's Flawed Methods 

    Today’s economics research — as it is pursued, and taught, by leading mainstream economists — rests on a scientific method that is borrowed from natural science and builds on positivism-empiricism-falsificationism. For a critical analysis see Hoppe, H.-H. (2006), Austrian Rationalism in the Age of the Decline of Positivism, in: The Economics and Ethics of Private Property. Studies in Political Economy and Philosophy, 2nd edition, Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, US Alabama, pp. 347 – 379. This approach, used in economics, does not only suffer from logical inconsistencies, its embedded skepticism and relativism has, in fact, has let economics astray. 

    Under the influence of positivism-empiricism-falsificationism economic theory – in particular monetary theory and financial market theory – has become the intellectual stirrup-holder of central banking, legitimizing the issuance of fiat money, the policy of manipulating the interest rate, the idea of making the financial system ‘safer’ through regulation.

    In this vein, Mr Draghi praises especially the independence of central banks — for it would shield central bankers from destabilizing political outside influence. One really wonders how this argument — one-sided as it is — could find acceptance, especially in view of the fact that independent central banks have caused the great crisis in the first place.

    The Central Bank's Many Friends

    Why is there hardly any public opposition to Mr Draghi’s narrative? Well, a great deal of experts on monetary policy — coming mostly from government sponsored universities and research institutes — tends to be die-hard supporters of central banking. The majority of them would not find any fundamental, that is economic or ethic, flaw with it.

    These so-called “monetary policy experts,” devoting so much time and energy for becoming and remaining an expert on monetary policy, unhesitatingly favor and accept without reservation the very principles on which central banking rests: the state’s coercive money production monopoly and all the measures to assert and defend it.

    The upshot of such a mindset is this: “Once the apparatus is established, its future development will be shaped by what those who have chosen to serve it regard as its needs,”Hayek, F. A. v. (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, p. 291. as F.A. Hayek explained the irrepressible expansionary nature of a monopolistic government agency – like a central bank.

    Experts, keenly catering to the needs of the state and the banks, will make monetary policy increasingly complex and incomprehensible to the general public. Just think about the confusing abbreviations the ECB uses such as, say, APP, QE, CBPP, OMT, LTRO, TLTRO, ELA etc.APP = Asset Purchase Programme, QE = quantitative easing (issuing new money by purchasing bonds), CBPP = Covered Bond Purchase Programme, OMT = Outright Monetary Transactions, LTRO = Long-term Refinancing Operations, TLTRO = Targeted Long-term Refinancing Operations, ELA = Emergency Liquidity Assistance. In this way central bankers effectively sneak themselves out from public and parliamentary control.

    Has the ECB Violated its Mandate? 

    It comes therefore as no surprise Mr Draghi hails “non-standard policy measures” such as quantitative easing through which the central bank subsidizes financially ailing governments and banks in particular. Mr Draghi, however, does not leave it at that. He also suggests that monetary policy should shake off remaining restrictions that hamper policy maker’s discretion:

    [W]hen the world changes as it did ten years ago, policies, especially monetary policy, need to be adjusted. Such an adjustment, never easy, requires unprejudiced, honest assessment of the new realities with clear eyes, unencumbered by the defence of previously held paradigms that have lost any explanatory power.

    These remarks come presumably because the German Constitutional Court has found indications that the ECB’s government bond purchases may violate EU law and has asked the European Court of Justice to make a ruling. The German judges say that ECB bond buys may go beyond the central bank's mandate and inhibit euro zone members' activities.

    The issue is no doubt delicate: If the ECB is prohibited from buying government bonds (let alone reverse its purchases), all hell may break loose in the euro area: Many government and banks would find it increasingly difficult to roll-over their maturing debt and take on new loans at affordable interest rates. The euro project would immediately find itself in hot water.

    Without a monetary policy of ultra-low interest rates and bailing out struggling borrowers by printing up new money (or promising to do so, if needed) the euro project would already have gone belly up. So far the ECB has indeed successfully concealed that the pipe dream of successfully creating and running a single fiat currency has failed.

    The crucial question in this context is, however: What has changed in economics in the last ten years? Unfortunately, economists that follows the doctrine of positivism-empiricism-falsificationism feel encouraged to question, even reject, the idea that there are immutable economic laws, preferring the notion that ‘things change’ that ‘everything is possible’.

    However, sound economics tells us that there are iron laws of human action. For instance, a rise in the quantity of money does not make an economy richer, it merely reduces the marginal utility of the money unit, thus reducing its purchasing power; or: suppressing the interest rate through the central bank must result in malinvestments and boom and bust.

    In other words: Sound economics tells us that central bankers do not pursue the greater good. They debase the currency; slyly redistribute income and wealth; benefit some groups at the expense of others; help the state to expand, to become a deep state at the expense of individual freedom; make people run into ever greater indebtedness.

    What central bankers really do is cause a "planned chaos." Unfortunately, the damages they create — such as, say, inflation, speculation, recession, mass unemployment etc. — are regularly and falsely attributed to the workings of the free market, thereby discouraging and eroding peoples’ confidence in private initiative and free enterprise.

    The failure of such interventionism — of which central bank monetary policy is an example par excellence — does not deter its supporters. On the contrary: They feel emboldened to pursue their interventionist course ever more boldly and aggressively to achieve their desired objectives. Mr Draghi made a case in point when he said in July 2012:

    “[W]e think the euro is irreversible” and “the ECB is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve the euro. And believe me, it will be enough.”Draghi, M., Verbatim of the remarks made by Mario Draghi, speech held at the Global Investment Conference in London, 26 July 2012. Hayek’s warning in his book Fatal Conceit (1988) goes unheard: “The curious task of economics is to demonstrate to men how little they really know about what they imagine they can design."Hayek, F. A. v. (1988), Fatal Conceit. The Errors of Socialism, edited by W. W. Bartley, III, Routledge, London, p. 76.

    Mr Draghi’s speech should not convince us that monetary policy rests on sound economics, or that the ECB works for the greater good. If anything, it shows that economics has been twisted and deformed to service the needs of the state and its central bank – which increasingly erodes what little is left of the free market to keep the fiat money system going.

    Holding up the fiat euro will result in a coercive redistribution of income and wealth among people, within and across national borders, to an extent historically unprecedented in times of piece. As a tool of an effectively anti-democratic policy, the single European currency will remain a source of interminable conflict, injustice, and it will be a drag on peoples’ prosperity. 

    Not Even Junk Will Fetch High Interest Rates Anymore

    Not Even Junk Will Fetch High Interest Rates Anymore

    The Federal Reserve tries and tries and just can’t muster up some price-tag ripping price inflation. Blowing up its balance sheet from $900 billion to $4.5 trillion would have seemed to send us to Zimbabwe, but no, prices just won’t cooperate with the monetary masterminds toiling away in the Eccles Building.

    MarketWatch’s Caroline Baum says Fed Chairs used to call these things conundrums. However, “Conundrums are a thing of the past. Nowadays, Fed Chairwoman Janet Yellen has an explanation — an excuse, really — for almost anything, from the atypical behavior of asset prices to inconsistencies in economic relationships,” writes Baum.

    We’re told by President Trump that we’re at full employment, yet prices (the way the Fed measures them anyway) can’t get to the 2 percent increase level Yellen et. al. considers nirvana.

    Baum writes that the Fed called price changes “transitory” then they were “definitional challenges” followed by “idiosyncratic factors,” such as “a precipitous drop in the price of wireless telecommunications services this year.”

    It’s in all the economic textbooks: Nothing stops inflation like a drop in cell phone fees.

    This summer, private economists are pointing to drops in hotel rates as depressing CPI and whatnot. However, Ms. Baum knows, “Inflation is a monetary phenomenon. When the Fed expands its balance sheet through asset purchases, it has no control over where that newly created money will go: toward the purchase of goods and services; or into financial assets, such as stocks, junk bonds or housing.”

    She continues, “The Fed’s asset purchases lower risk-free Treasury rates, encouraging investors to reach for yield and buy riskier assets.

    “Because asset prices aren’t part of official inflation measures, and because identifying an asset bubble is beyond their scope, central bankers eschew using monetary policy to respond to them.”

    The Fed is not alone in its bubble enabling. A Bloomberg Businessweek headline screams, “Even the Junkiest Sovereign Debt Now Pays Less Than 6%.” with the subtitle naming the culprit, “Central bank buying has distorted the market and reduced yields on the lowest-rated debt.”

    It’s not just those cranky Austrians calling central bankers on the carpet for their monetary mischief these days. Everyone knows, is holding their breath, and hoping for the best.

    Natasha Doff explains,

    The junkiest emerging-market bonds yield less now than U.S. Treasury bills did as recently as 1999. Yields on state debt of Mongolia, Ukraine and Belarus -- at seven levels below investment grade, among the world's lowest ranked -- have dropped under 6 percent in the past two months.

    It is as Ms. Baum writes, “Asset prices are a symptom; excessive credit growth is the cause.”

    William White wrote in a 2009 paper that bubble episodes have the following in common: leverage, speculation and declining credit standards.

    For instance money losing Tesla looked to sell $1.5 billion of junk bond debt and ended up selling $1.8 billion because the demand was so high for it's B- rated paper.

    "I won't call it a bubble," said Andrew Feltus, co-head of high yield and bank loans at Amundi Pioneer Asset Management in Boston told Reuters. "The (market) fundamentals are pretty good."

    Some would disagree. According to ValueWalk, “Tesla, Inc. is an over-hyped, lousy company, from a financial perspective, that is destined to go bankrupt.”

    Famed Short-seller Jim Chanos said last year the announced $2.6 billion merger with SolarCity Corp. will make Tesla Motors Inc. a "walking insolvency."

    A “walking insolvency” can borrow more than it wants at 5.3%; now that’s a conundrum.

    Douglas French is former president of the Mises Institute, author of Early Speculative Bubbles & Increases in the Money Supply, and author of Walk Away: The Rise and Fall of the Home-Ownership Myth.

    Mises Wire
    enAugust 29, 2017

    Are Central Banks Nationalising the Economy?

    Are Central Banks Nationalising the Economy?

    The FT recently ran an article that states that “leading central banks now own a fifth of their governments’ total debt.”

    The figures are staggering.

    Without any recession or crisis, major central banks are purchasing more than $200 billion a month in government and private debt, led by the ECB and the Bank of Japan.The Federal Reserve owns more than 14% of the US total public debt.The ECB and BOJ balance sheets exceed 35% and 70% of their GDP.The Bank of Japan is now a top 10 shareholder in 90% of the Nikkei.The ECB owns 9.2% of the European corporate bond market and more than 10% of the main European countries’ total sovereign debt.The Bank of England owns between 25% and 30% of the UK’s sovereign debt.

    A recent report by Nick Smith, an analyst at CLSA, warns of what he calls ”the nationalization of the secondary market.”

    The Bank of Japan, with its ultra-expansionary policy, which only expands its balance sheet, is on course to become the largest shareholder of the Nikkei 225’s largest companies. In fact, the Japanese central bank already accounts for 60% of the ETFs market (Exchange traded funds) in Japan.

    What can go wrong? Overall, the central bank not only generates greater imbalances and a poor result in a “zombified” economy as the extremely loose policies perpetuate imbalances, weaken money velocity, and incentivize debt and malinvestment.

    Believing that this policy is harmless because “there is no inflation” and unemployment is low is dangerous. The government issues massive amounts of debt and cheap money promotes overcapacity and poor capital allocation. As such, productivity growth collapses, real wages fall and purchasing power of currencies fall, driving the real cost of living up and debt to grow more than real GDP. That is why, as we have shown in previous articles, total debt has soared to 325% of GDP while zombie companies reach crisis-high levels, according to the Bank of International Settlements.

    Government-issued liabilities monetized by the central bank are not high-quality assets, they are an IOU that is transferred to the next generations, and it will be repaid in three ways: with massive inflation, with a series of financial crises, or with large unemployment. Currency purchasing power destruction is not a growth policy, it is stealing from future generations. The “placebo” effect of spending today the Net Present Value of those IOUs means that, as GDP, productivity and real disposable income do not improve, at least as much as the debt issued, we are creating a time bomb of economic imbalances that only grows and will explode sometime in the future. The fact that the evident ball of risk is delayed another year does not mean that it does not exist.

    The government is not issuing “productive money” just a promise of higher revenues from higher taxes, higher prices or confiscation of wealth in the future. Money supply growth is a loan that government borrows but we, citizens, pay. The payment comes with the destruction of purchasing power and confiscation of wealth via devaluation and inflation. The “wealth effect” of stocks and bonds rising is inexistent for the vast majority of citizens, as more than 90% of average household wealth is in deposits.

    In fact, massive monetization of debt is just a way of perpetuating and strengthening the crowding-out effect of the public sector over the private sector. It is a de facto nationalization. Because the central bank does not go “bankrupt,” it just transfers its financial imbalances to private banks, businesses, and families.

    The central bank can “print” all the money it wants and the government benefits from it, but the ones that suffer financial repression are the rest. By generating subsequent financial crises through loose monetary policies and always being the main beneficiary of the boom, and the bust, the public sector comes out from these crises more powerful and more indebted, while the private sector suffers the crowding-out effect in crisis times, and the taxation and wealth confiscation effect in expansion times.

    No wonder that government spending to GDP is now almost 40% in the OECD and rising, the tax burden is at all-time highs and public debt soars.

    Monetization is a perfect system to nationalize the economy passing all the risks of excess spending and imbalances to taxpayers. And it always ends badly. Because two plus two does not equal twenty-two. As we tax the productive to perpetuate and subsidize the unproductive, the impact on purchasing power and wealth destruction is exponential.

    To believe that this time will be different and governments will spend all that massive “very expensive free money” wisely is simply delusional. The government has all the incentives to overspend as its goal is to maximize budget and increase bureaucracy as means of power. It also has all the incentives to blame its mistakes on an external enemy. Governments always blame someone else for their mistakes. Who lowers rates from 10% to 1%? Governments and central banks. Who is blamed for taking “excessive risk” when it explodes? You and me. Who increases money supply, demands “credit flow,” and imposes financial repression because “savings are too high”? Governments and central banks. Who is blamed when it explodes? Banks for “reckless lending” and “de-regulation”.

    Of course, governments can print all the money they want, what they cannot do is convince you and me that it has a value, that the price and amount of money they impose is real just because the government says so. Hence lower real investment, and lower productivity. Citizens and companies are not crazy for not falling into the trap of low rates and high asset inflation. They are not amnesiac.

    It is called financial repression for a reason, and citizens will always try to escape from theft.

    What is the “hook” to let us buy into it? Stock markets rise, bonds fall, and we are led to believe that asset inflation is a reflection of economic strength.

    Then, when the central bank policy stops working — either from lack of confidence or because it is simply part of the liquidity — and markets fall to their deserved valuations, many will say that it is the fault of “speculators,” not the central speculator.

    When it erupts, you can bet your bottom dollar that the consensus will blame markets, hedge funds, lack of regulation and not enough intervention. Perennial intervention mistakes are “solved” with more intervention. Government won on the way up, and wins on the way down. Like a casino, the house always wins.

    Meanwhile, the famous structural reforms that had been promised disappear like bad memories.

    It is a clever Machiavellian system to end free markets and disproportionately benefit governments through the most unfair of competitions: having unlimited access to money and credit and none of the risks. And passing the bill to everyone else.

    If you think it does not work because the government does not do a lot more, you are simply dreaming.

    Originally published at DLacalle.com

    How Rand Paul Can Free Americans from the Fed

    How Rand Paul Can Free Americans from the Fed

    Ever since entering the Senate, Rand Paul has continued his father’s work in advocating for an audit of the Federal Reserve. This week, writing for the Daily Caller, Senator Paul renewed his efforts, illustrating how the recent era of unconventional monetary policy has made an audit all the more important:

    In 2009, then-Fed Chairman Ben Bernanke was able to refuse to tell Congress who received over two trillion in Fed loans, and it took congressional action and a Bloomberg lawsuit to force the Fed to reveal the details of what it did in more than 21,000 transactions involving trillions of dollars during the 2008 financial crisis.  A one-time audit of the Fed’s emergency lending mandated by Congress revealed even more about the extent to which the Fed put taxpayers on the hook.

    When pushed to defend the lack of transparency for the Federal Reserve, officials like Janet Yellen and Treasury Secretary Steve Mnuchin point to the myth of the Fed independence — a position that requires outright ignorance of the history of America’s central bank and the executive branch. Of course it’s quite usual for the Senate to base the merits of legislation entirely off of fallacious arguments, so they have continued to be the legislative body holding up a Fed audit with little indication they are prepared to move.

    Given that reality, it is time for Senator Rand Paul to change his approach and introduce another piece of legislation from his father’s archives: the Free Competition in Currency Act.

    While not as catchy as “End the Fed”, this piece of legislation – inspired by the work of F.A. Hayek – was perhaps Ron Paul’s most radical pieces of legislation. The idea was quite simple: eliminate legal tender laws mandating the use of US Dollars and remove the taxes Federal and State governments place on alternative currencies — such as gold and silver. While the original legislation did apply to “tokens,” an updated version should explicitly include the growing market of cryptocurrencies as a good with monetary value that should not be taxed.

    What this would do is create a more even playing field between the dollar and alternative currencies, allowing an easy way for Americans to safeguard their wealth if they ever have reason to doubt the wisdom of the Federal Reserve’s policies. Just as Senator Paul advocated for the ability of Americans to be able to opt-out of the failing Obamacare system, this bill would grant Americans a lifeboat should the weaknesses inherent with the Fed’s fiat money regime expose themselves.

    Unlike most examples of monetary policy reforms, which tend to be the products of ivory tower echo chambers, competition in currency would reflect active political trends. In recent years, states like Texas, Utah, and – in 2017 – Arizona have passed laws allowing the use of silver and gold for use in transactions. Meanwhile, other countries have looked to embrace the potential of cryptocurrencies for their monetary regimes. This makes this not only an idea that is good on paper, but one whose time has come.

    As alluded to before, simply because a policy makes sense does not mean the Senate will act on it. That doesn’t mean the conversation and debate isn’t worth having. While it may still be on the horizon, there has been a steady drumbeat in Washington for the Federal Reserve to face some sort of reform. For two Congressional sessions in a row, the House has passed legislation explicitly calling for the Fed to embrace a “rules-based monetary system.” While this approach may sound better than today’s PhD standard, it doesn’t solve the problems inherent with central banking and fiat money.

    Monetary rules such as “NGD Targeting” – which has the support of a rare coalition including the Cato Institute, Mercatus Center, Christina Romer, and Paul Krugman — should never be seen as a “reasonable compromise” for those skeptical about the Fed. Instead it’s simply another way of disguising central planning in a way to make it more palpable to the public, and therefore more difficult to stop. By putting this bill out there, Rand Paul can help frame the debate and bring a real solution to the table. Something that wouldn't force the Fed to change a single thing, only making them compete on the market like the producer of other good or service. 

    After all, as is the case with healthcare, or shoes, the best sort of “monetary policy” is competition on the market. Not one dictated by government. 

    Mises Wire
    enAugust 23, 2017